This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, December 29, 2014
Is Economics Already Open Access?
We just got the December 2014 issue of The American Economics Review. It took me about 10 minutes to find ungated versions of all the papers.
Friday, December 26, 2014
An appreciation of E.P. Thompson
This is The American Conservative's Christmas reading list. Benjamin Schwarz, the national editor of The American Conservative, chose E.P. Thompson's The Making of the English Working Class.
"Steeped in English literature—see the constant, apposite, and often starling allusions to Bunyan and Byron, Defoe and the Bible—Thompson wrote powerfully, concretely, plangently, with an exquisite sense of cadence and rhythm. That style deepens this elegiac book, elevating it to a masterpiece of literature as well as of scholarship. This is a work, Thompson unabashedly makes clear, about history’s losers, and in its embrace of the losers, as well as in other ways, The Making of the English Working Class is a profoundly anti-progressive book. Its protagonists’ values and their 50-year struggle to resist being turned into a proletariat may have seemed merely primitive and retrograde to strident Marxists (and may seem so to progressives of all stripes today), but Thompson’s historical imagination and sympathy allowed him to see the value, and the tragedy, of lost causes."
"Steeped in English literature—see the constant, apposite, and often starling allusions to Bunyan and Byron, Defoe and the Bible—Thompson wrote powerfully, concretely, plangently, with an exquisite sense of cadence and rhythm. That style deepens this elegiac book, elevating it to a masterpiece of literature as well as of scholarship. This is a work, Thompson unabashedly makes clear, about history’s losers, and in its embrace of the losers, as well as in other ways, The Making of the English Working Class is a profoundly anti-progressive book. Its protagonists’ values and their 50-year struggle to resist being turned into a proletariat may have seemed merely primitive and retrograde to strident Marxists (and may seem so to progressives of all stripes today), but Thompson’s historical imagination and sympathy allowed him to see the value, and the tragedy, of lost causes."
Does History Need a Manifesto?
Peter Mandler and Deborah Cohen review The History Manifesto by Jo Guldi and David Armitage. The review provides an interesting and optimistic assessment of the current state of the discipline of history.
Here is an earlier review by Pseudoerasmus, focusing on the books false claims about economic historians.
Here is an earlier review by Pseudoerasmus, focusing on the books false claims about economic historians.
Thursday, December 25, 2014
Tuesday, December 23, 2014
Cotton, Slavery and Economic Growth
Recently, several historians (Edward Baptist and Sven Beckert) have
attempted to make slavery and cotton the driving force behind American economic
growth in the nineteenth century. I believe that they present a misleading view
of economic growth and the relationship between slavery and economic growth.
1.
Slavery was predominately associated with one
product: cotton. Cotton was a very important crop. It is true, as Beckert points
out, that cotton accounted for over half of U.S. exports on the eve of the
Civil War. But exports were only about 9 % of GDP. Similarly, cotton accounted
for about 23 % of income in the South, but the South accounted for only 26% of
U.S. income. See D. A. Irwin, “The Optimal Tax on Antebellum U.S. cotton
Exports,” Journal of International Economics 60(2003):287) Ultimately, the
value of cotton production was equal to about 6% of GDP. The attempts to make
cotton the driving force of the American economy misses one of the most
important finding of economic historians: do not get too focused on a single
sector of an economy (see Fogel on the railroads and McCloskey on the textile
industry in England). There is no Rostovian engine of growth.
3.
Slavery appears to have had a negative effect on
long run trends in per capita GDP. The more a region depended on slave labor in
the past the lower its per capita income now.
You can go to measuringworth.com and graph the log of per capita GDP from 1800 to 1900. Does it appear to you that the rate of growh declined after 1865?
Wednesday, December 17, 2014
If all else fails just make it up
In the Washington
Post today Jim Tankersley reports on the negative influence of finance on
the economy. He reports that “In perhaps the
starkest illustration, economists from Harvard University and the University of
Chicago wrote in a recent paper that every dollar a worker earns in a
research field spills over to make the economy $5 better off. Every dollar a
similar worker earns in finance comes with a drain, making the economy 60 cents
worse off.” I clicked on the link to the paper (Lockwood BB,
Nathanson CG, Weyl GE. Taxation
and the Allocation of Talent). As best I can tell it says no such thing. It
seems to me that the authors are quite explicit that they do not have such
estimates of the spillover effects of different occupations. They use a variety
of guesses about what they might be to examine the implications of their model.
More new "history" of capitalism
Sven Beckert has an essay in the Chronicle Review, markting his new book.
Historians “observe,
quite rightly, that the world we live in cannot be understood without coming to
terms with the long history of capitalism—a process that has arguably unfolded
over more than half a millennium. They are further encouraged by the
all-too-frequent failings of
economists, who have tended to naturalize particular economic
arrangements by defining the "laws" of their development with
mathematical precision and preferring short-term over long-term perspectives.”
The need to offer some vague critique of economics in everything
they write is one of the most tiresome features of the new historians of
capitalism. I suggest that he take a look at some of the work by economists
that examines the influence of differences in institutions and endowments on
long term economic performance: North, Sokolof and Engerman, and Nunn would be
good places to start.
“What distinguishes
today’s historians of capitalism is that they insist on its contingent nature,
tracing how it has changed over time as it has revolutionized societies,
technologies, states, and many if not all facets of life.”
Who does this distinguish them from? Business historians have
frequently made such distinctions, writing about proprietary capitalism and
managerial capitalism, or just varieties of capitalism. Or, consider the work
on the evolution of monopoly capitalism by Marxist scholars. Most of the work by new institutional economic historians is about how capitalist economies have differed from place to place and eveolved over time.
“For too long, many
historians saw no problem in the opposition between capitalism and slavery.
They depicted the history of American capitalism without slavery, and slavery
as quintessentially noncapitalist. Instead of analyzing it as the modern
institution that it was, they described it as premodern.
Some scholars have always
disagree with such accounts. In the 1930s and 1940s, C.L.R. James and Eric
Williams argued for the centrality of slavery to capitalism, though their
findings were largely ignored. Nearly half a century later, two American
economists, Stanley L. Engerman and Robert William Fogel, observed in their
controversial book Time on the Cross (Little, Brown, 1974) the modernity and
profitability of slavery in the United States. Now a flurry of books and conferences are building
on those often unacknowledged foundations.”
Why don’t the people doing the new history of capitalism start acknowledging
these foundations?
Special Issue on Piketty's Capital
The British Journal of Sociology has a special issue on Piketty's Capital. All the articles are available free of charge.
Wednesday, December 10, 2014
Happy Birthday to The Junto
The Junto is celebrating its second birthday. I am not an early Americanist, but The Junto is one of my favorite blogs. The contributors are thoughtful and passionate about what they do. Anyone interested in American history, doing history, or teaching history should read what they have to say.
Tuesday, December 9, 2014
The Depression of 1921?
The “Depression of 1921” has been receiving a lot of
attention recently (Krugman,
Selgin,
Murphy,
and Sumner)
mostly in response to James Grant’s The
Forgotten Depression:1921: The Crash That Cured Itself. The argument of the
book is that the economy recovered more quickly because neither the federal
government nor the Federal Reserve attempted to pursue activist policies. I am
skeptical that 1921 is a useful case to generalize from.
It was a post war recession, much like the one after World
War II. Most business cycle movements have been associated with busts after
periods of credit expansion (see the recent work of Alan Taylor et al). In those
cases it was households and businesses that borrowed and spent during the boom.
Consequently, when the bust comes, businesses and consumers struggle to repay
their debts. Businesses fail and consumers default. Even consumers who do
not go bankrupt reduce their current spending to avoid default (see Martha
Olney). As businesses and households default the value of bank assets fall and
banks fail. The bank failures result in decreases in the money supply (Friedman
and Schwartz) and disintermediation (Bernanke). In other words, it creates a real mess when people take on excessive amounts of debt, especially when they use that debt to bid up the prices of assets like stocks or real estate.
In terms of increases in output and prices, war time booms
look similar to credit fueled booms, but the government is the one borrowing
and spending. The end of the boom does not necessarily lead to a financial
crisis or reductions in consumption and investment. Granted government borrowing can also create a mess, particulalry if people begin to doubt its willingness or ability to pay, but that hasn't really been an issue for the U.S.
I also have a problem with calling this a depression. I know
that there is no universally accepted definition of the term depression. And I
know that Grant is not the first to refer to this episode as a depression. But
we completely lose any distinction between a recession and a depression if this
was a depression. Neither the length nor the severity of the decline in real
GDP warrant the term depression.
Saturday, December 6, 2014
Business History Conference
The Business History Conference launched its new website yesterday. In addition to the usual stuff about meetings it has an extensive list of links for research in business history and syllabi and other resources for teaching business history and business history related courses.
Thursday, December 4, 2014
Claudia Goldin in Saudi Arabia
The New York Times reports on how the economic historian Claudia Goldin tries to help Saudi women enter the labor force while following the prime directive (see paragraph 5).
Tuesday, December 2, 2014
The Fall and Rise of Economic History
Jeremy Adelman and Jonathan Levy describe "The Fall and Rise of Economic History" in the Chronicle of Higher Education
I still hope that economic history will regain a prominent position in both economics and history and that economists and historians will be able to move forward together.
I found this essay particularly interesting because both Jeremy
Adelman and I studied economic history at the LSE in 1984-85. If I
remember correctly, we were the first cohort to do a new M.Sc. program focusing on
Third World economic history. He went on to get his PhD. In history (Oxford); I
went on to get a Ph. D. in economics (Washington University).
I remember a seminar where Jeremy presented the work he was
doing on Argentina. The first person to speak was one of the older professors
in the department, very much a traditional historian. He said, “That is political
history. This is a seminar in economic history.” He then leaned back, laced his
fingers over his stomach, and looked around the room, smiling as if he had just
said all that needed to be said. I know he did not speak for all the professors
present, but it was still a very discouraging moment. Like Jeremy, I was interested
in economic questions but didn’t believe it was possible to leave politics and
ideology out of the answer. I had also just started to read Douglass North’s
work on institutions and ideology and thought it might provide the way forward.
I decided to pursue a degree in economics. Since then, I think economists (for
example, North, Wallis, McCloskey, Mokyr) have continued to make progress in
reintegrating politics, the law, and culture into the study of economic history.
I have, on the other hand, been very disappointed in the “new
history of capitalism” that has arisen in history departments. I first thought
that this might be the moment for a much needed reunion of economists and
historians, but it quickly became clear that that was not what the new history
of capitalism was about. Instead of confronting the work of economists directly
it is generally ignored or dismissed. People throw around terms like homo
economicus, suggesting that economists all think that people care only about
maximizing their material wealth and that they do so with perfect information.
They seem to believe that the recent financial crisis has undermined the
credibility of economic theory because things did not work out well, while a
student in any decent principles of economics class could show you the
prisoners’ dilemma and explain to you that economic models do not all conclude
that everything will work out for the best. The quality of the historical research is
secondary to the author’s stance against capitalism (which is not defined) and
economics.