Wednesday, December 9, 2020

Thaler and Twitter on Auctions and Nudges

 

Richard Thaler has an essay in the New York Times about Covid shots in which he advocates a combination of auctions and “nudges.” As always there are interesting responses on Twitter. I saw several people suggesting that it was affine illustration of the evils of modern economics. I have a hard time seeing that.

 

First, lets start with the auction part. Thaler starts from the position that markets should not be used to allocate the shots. In the market solution, the shots would those who have the greatest willingness and ability to pay. He says that obviously that shouldn’t be done, but he notes that if market prices are not used to ration the limited number of shots then some other means of rationing must be found. He seems to want a distribution plan something like I have seen advocated elsewhere: those most at risk, elderly and health care workers, go first. After them others are generally prioritized in terms of their risk and their role in providing for public health and safety. So far, hard to see the evil. Its also hard to see the economics. The premise that markets should not be used to allocate the good is generally not one associated with economics. Economics does appear in the observation that with a price that is below the market equilibrium there will be shortage. The quantity of shots demanded will exceed the quantity of shots supplied. But it hardly seems controversial or evil to note that there is going to be a shortage of shots for the first few months.

 

The evil appears to arise from his suggestion that a small number of shots should be auctioned off to the highest bidder and the money used to benefit those who have been harmed by the virus. But what is Thaler’s argument for this plan. He suggests that the rich will find a way to obtain the shots, but if you auction them to the highest bidder that the money the rich are paying will go to the government and then to needy people in society. This argument is actually similar to one that has been made for elite colleges. Auction off places at Harvard, Yale, etc. to the highest bidder and use the money for scholarships to benefit low income students. The alternative seems to be that places are auctioned off to the highest bidder for the benefit of fencing, tennis, and crew coaches. You can, of course argue with multiple parts of his argument, but the claim that wealthy people are going to find a way to get the shots one or another doesn’t seem that controversial, and the suggestion that had might as well benefit from that hardly seems evil.

 

If there is a part that I do disagree with it is my usual complaint about Thaler: nudges are just old wine in new bottles.

What should we do to ensure that most people eventually get the shot?

Traditional economist: Lower the cost and increase the benefit of getting the shot.

Thaler: No. You should nudge them?

Traditional economist: Nudge them?

Thaler: Yes, make it easier for them to get the shot and give them some reward when they do.

Traditional economist: Isn’t that what I said?

Monday, November 23, 2020

The Green Books and American Economic History

 

I finally had a chance to read the NBER working paper by Lisa Cook, Maggie E.C. Jones, David Rosé, and  Trevon D. Logan on The Green Books and the Geography of Segregation in Public Accommodations. They identified the locations of businesses listed in the Green Books and then analyzed how they changed over time as well as how the locations were related to other characteristics of the areas where  they were located.  Their primary conclusions are described in the abstract:

Jim Crow segregated African Americans and whites by law and practice. The causes and implications of the associated de jure and de facto residential segregation have received substantial attention from scholars, but there has been little empirical research on racial discrimination in public accommodations during this time period. We digitize the Negro Motorist Green Books, important historical travel guides aimed at helping African Americans navigate segregation in the pre-Civil Rights Act United States. We create a novel panel dataset that contains precise geocoded locations of over 4,000 unique businesses that provided non-discriminatory service to African American patrons between 1938 and 1966. Our analysis reveals several new facts about discrimination in public accommodations that contribute to the broader literature on racial segregation. First, the largest number of Green Book establishments were found in the Northeast, while the lowest number were found in the West. The Midwest had the highest number of Green Book establishments per black resident and the South had the lowest. Second, we combine our Green Book estimates with newly digitized county-level estimates of hotels to generate the share of non-discriminatory formal accommodations. Again, the Northeast had the highest share of non-discriminatory accommodations, with the South following closely behind. Third, for Green Book establishments located in cities for which the Home Owner’s Loan Corporation (HOLC) drew residential security maps, the vast majority (nearly 70 percent) are located in the lowest-grade, redlined neighborhoods. Finally, Green Book presence tends to correlate positively with measures of material well-being and economic activity.

 

 

 The paper also made me wonder about the the Green Book in relation to places that I have lived. You can view digitized Green Books through the New York Public Library. I looked at the 1959 issue for Fredericksburg, Virginia and Nebraska, where I am originally from.

 

Here are some pictures of the Fredericksburg hotels listed in the Green Books: The Hotel McGuire and the Rappahannock Hotel. They were located across Princess Anne Street from each other near the corner of Princess Anne and Wolfe Street. It was an ideal location in several ways Princess Anne was part of the original Route 1. The Greyhound Bus Station was located on the same corner, and the train station was one block south.

 


 





 

 

Both Hotels were Black owned, and it was a predominately Black neighborhood. Shiloh Baptist Church (New Site) was next door to the McGuire and Mount Zion Baptist Church was less than a block away. Here is an article from the Free Lance Star with people reminiscing about growing up in the neighborhood.

 

 

I also looked at the locations for Nebraska. I was not surprised to see locations near Omaha. I was surprised to see locations in Chadron, Valentine and Ainsworth near the South Dakota border. These are pretty rural parts of Nebraska even now. 

 


According to the 1960 Census, the three counties that these towns were located in had a Black population of 19. I suspect the location of these hotels had to do with the fact that U.S. Route 20 goes through each of these towns. Route 20 goes from Newport Oregon and passes through Idaho, Wyoming, Nebraska, and Iowa before reaching Chicago and, ultimately, Boston. If you were anywhere in the Pacific Northwest and wanted to go to Chicago, Detroit or further east, Route 20 would likely have been your route. 


(The map is from the  Green Book working paper)

 


The Fredericksburg and Nebraska locations were both listed in the Green Book and both were located on what were, at the time, important highways, but that it pretty much where the similarities end. The Hotels in Fredericksburg were Black owned, located ina Black neighborhood, and catered to a Black clientele. I am not absolutely cetain, but I suspect that the motels in Valentine, Chadron and Ainsworth were not segregated. As best I can tell the Midwest Hotel in Ainsworth was white owned was listed in the American Hotel Associations Red Book. 


 (I'm not sure this is the hotel in the Green Book. Here it says the Three Oaks Auto  Court; in the Green Book there is an Oak Court. In any case its a cool old motel.)

It is less obvious why the rural Nebraska hotels were accommodating enough to be included in the Green Book. I grew up in small towns in Nebraska in the 1960s. I’m reluctant to believe that racism was just not an issue. I never saw any Black people but that didn’t keep people from being prejudiced against them.  My uncle lived in Valentine for awhile, its just across the border from the Rosebud Reservation and I suspect its residents would not tell you that racism is absent from the area. On the other hand, pressure to conform to norms or laws that enforced segregation were probably not as great as they were in places, like Fredericksburg, where there was actually more interaction with Black people. In addition, the profit margin on a small rural hotel may have made it difficult to turn anyone away.

Wednesday, November 11, 2020

Amazon and Sears

 

I was talking to some students today about how Sears expanded from selling watches by mail to selling everything by mail. In the early twentieth century you could even by a house from Sears. We started talking about how Amazon had gone from selling books to selling everything, and one student told me you can now buy tiny houses on Amazon, which I had not known.

 

Here are some Sears houses

 


 

To see more Sears houses go here

Here are some houses available on Amazon

 

 


 


If you want to see more homes on Amazon just search Amazon.

 

Amazon is currently being prosecuted for violation of European antitrust laws. Sears on the other hand has recently gone through bankruptcy, though it’s not clear that there is actually something there to save.

 

Amazon has incredible size and market power right now, but many examples from business history suggest that these are hard to hold on to in the long run.

 

 

By the way, you could also buy a Sears motorcycle (with European styling and performance) 


And, yes, you can now buy motorcycles on Amazon as well.