This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, December 25, 2017
Monday, December 18, 2017
The Mellon Tax Cuts of the 1920s
Opponents of tax cuts claim that the large income tax cuts in
the 1920s caused increased inequality and the Great Depression. For instance, Robert
S. McElvaine writes in “I’m a
Depression historian. The GOP tax bill is straight out of 1929” Washington
Post’s PostEverything Perspective
that
The crash followed a
decade of Republican control of the federal government during which
trickle-down policies, including massive tax cuts for the rich, produced the
greatest concentration of income in the accounts of the richest 0.01 percent at
any time between World War I and 2007 (when trickle-down economics, tax cuts
for the hyper-rich, and deregulation again resulted in another economic
collapse).
In 1926, Calvin
Coolidge’s treasury secretary, Andrew Mellon, one of the world’s richest men,
pushed through a massive tax cut that would substantially contribute to the
causes of the Great Depression.
In that decade, the
mass-production American economy became dependent on mass consumption. For it
to work, the masses need a sufficient share of the national income to be able
to consume what is being produced.
Republican policies
in the ’20s instead pushed to concentrate more of the income at the top.
On the other hand, proponents of tax cuts have used the
1920s tax cuts (sometimes referred to as the Mellon after the Secretary of the
Treasury Andrew Mellon) to illustrate how tax cuts can fuel so much economic
growth that they generate increases in revenue. For instance, back in 2003, Veronique
de Rugy argued that
The decade of the
1920s had started with very high tax rates and an economic recession. Tax rates
were massively increased in 1917 at all income levels. Rates were increased
again in 1918. Real GNP fell in 1919, 1920, and 1921 with a total three-year
fall of 16 percent. (Deflation between 1920 and 1922 may also help explain the
drop in tax revenues in those years, evident in Table 1).
As tax rates were cut
in the mid-1920s, total tax revenues initially fell. But as the economy
responded and began growing quickly, revenues soared as incomes rose. By 1928,
revenues had surpassed the 1920 level even though tax rates had been
dramatically cut.
She also notes that Between
1922 and 1929, real gross national product grew at an annual average rate of
4.7 percent and the unemployment rate fell from 6.7 percent to 3.2
percent.
I am not persuaded that either of these stories clearly establishes
connections between cause (tax cuts) and effect (inequality, economic growth,
Great Depression).
Both stories attribute a great deal of economic influence to
a relatively small federal government. Prior to the Great Depression, the
federal revenue typically accounted for less than 5% of GDP.
Moreover,
income taxes accounted for only about half of federal revenue (Statistical Abstract
of the United States for 1926 Table No. 169) Neither opponents or proponents of
tax cuts explain how changes that are so
small relative to the whole economy could have effects as large as they suggest.
In addition, many of the changes during the 1920s were part of a reversion to pre-War patterns.The federal government lowered income tax rates during
the 1920s, but it lowered them from the rates that had been imposed during World
War I. By the end of the 1920s the top marginal rates were still almost double
what they had been before the War.
Source: http://eh.net/encyclopedia/the-u-s-economy-in-the-1920s/
Likewise, the available evidence suggests that inequality of
both income and wealth increased during the 1920s, but they were also moving
back toward the rates that had existed before the war.
Source Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. "Income inequality in the United States, 1913–1998." The Quarterly journal of economics 118, no. 1 (2003): 1-41.
From a longer run perspective, the rapid decline of World
War I and increase in the 1920s was a blip in a trend of decreasing inequality
that was not isolated to the U.S.
Moreover, taxes were cut for all income groups and both the amount and the share of taxes paid by lower income groups decreased.
Source: de Rugy
Even if there is not a clear connection between tax cuts and inequality, inequality did increase. Could that increase in inequality have led to underconsumption as
an important cause of the Great Depression? It seems unlikely.
Although inequality increased during the 1920s, it was not immiserating
working class people. After the recession of the early 1920s, real wages generally increased until the Great Depression.
Source: http://eh.net/encyclopedia/the-u-s-economy-in-the-1920s/
Dramatic decreases in consumption expenditures were certainly
a cause of the severity of the Great Depresion, but they were not an initiating
factor. Consumption fell after a
tightening of monetary policy and the stock market crash. Consumption fell
because of decreases in wealth and income, but also because of increases in uncertainty
about the future (Romer 1990, Romer
and Romer 2013) and because of the need to reduce current consumption to
make installment payments and avoid repossession (Olney
1999). The initial problems were exacerbated by continued bank failures and
decreases in the money supply. Economic historians continue to explore the
extent to which the problems in money and banking were the result of Federal
Reserve failures or problems with the international gold standard. Given the
small initial size of the federal government it should perhaps not be
surprising that economists tend to find the causes of the Great Depression in
monetary rather than fiscal policy.
The 4.7 percent rate of growth from 1922 to 1929 that de Rugy mentions is very
sensitive to beginning and end dates. Much of it comes from very high rates at the
beginning and the end. The annualized growth rate from 1923 to 1928 was a much
less spectacular 2.8%.
It seem likely that the lower rates simply meant it was no
longer worthwhile for high income earners to incur the costs associated with
tax avoidance. This was primary the reason that Mellon gave for the tax cuts.
I'll try to keep an open mind, but I am not yet persuaded that the Mellon tax cuts were able to generate very large macroeconomic economic effects despite the relatively small role of the federal government generally and the federal income tax specifically prior to the Great Depression.
Thursday, December 14, 2017
Clegg on Capitalism and Slavery
I just ran across John Clegg’s "Credit
Market Discipline and Capitalist Slavery in Antebellum South
Carolina." Social Science History (2017): 1-34. Clegg got a lot of attention a couple
of years ago for "Capitalism
and Slavery." in which he criticized the approach of New
Historians of Capitalism, especially Edward Baptist. Clegg’s critique was based
in part on work that he had done on the role of credit among slaveholders in South
Carolina, and that work is presented more fully in this new paper.
Clegg follows Robert
Brenner in terms of focusing on competition for the means of production as
the driving force behind capitalist growth. Capitalists are forced to increase
productivity to survive as capitalists. Clegg’s twist is to add the need to use
credit to finance the purchase as land and slaves as the mechanism that drove
this competition in the South. He has interesting information about the
development of debtor creditor law and the extent to which slaveholders experienced
foreclosure.
Clegg explains that
I claim that the
ability of creditors to seize the land and slaves of insolvent debtors
compelled slave owners to specialize for the market and increase productivity.
It did so because most slave owners were in debt, and those who failed to repay
their debts at the going rate would end up losing their land and slaves, and
thus cease to be slave owners.
He concludes that
if the debt
constraint I am describing was operative, then identifiably capitalist
outcomes—market orientation, profit maximizing, technical innovation—are in an
important sense independent of mentality. This is because slave owners who were
not interested in specializing for the market, maximizing profit or adopting
cost-reducing innovations would end up losing their slaves to those who were.
On this view, capitalist patterns of behavior can be the unintended consequence
of competitive selection operating via credit markets
That description made me think of Armen Alchian’s Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory,
which made essentially the same argument in defense of economic theory. I should also mention John Nye’s "Lucky
fools and cautious businessmen: On entrepreneurship and the measurement of
entrepreneurial failure." The Vital One: Essays in Honor of
Jonathan RT Hughes. Research in Economic History 6 (1991): 131-52
which makes a similar sort of evolutionary argument regarding entrepreneurship.
P.S. If you weren't paying attention when Clegg's first paper came out you might to check out the Junto for some of the discussion it generated.
Tuesday, December 12, 2017
Friday, December 8, 2017
Hartman on Public Choice
Andrew Hartman has an essay at The Baffler arguing that “libertarianism is a political philosophy
shot through with white supremacy. Public choice theory, a technical language
nominally about human behavior and incentives, helps ensure that blacks remain
shackled.”
I have pointed out before that I am not a libertarian. I
have been critical of libertarians on several occasions (for instance, here
and here)
. I am not associated with George Mason, not paid by the Koch brothers, and not
really a big fan of James Buchanan. So why bother writing this? I do have an
interest in public choice, and I find the recent attempts to bind racism,
Buchanan, public choice, libertarianism, and the Koch brothers into a neat little bundle ridiculous.
Below are quotes from Hartman’s essay (in bold) and my
responses to them.
IN DECEMBER 1992, AN
OBSCURE ACADEMIC JOURNAL published an article by economists Alexander
Tabarrok and Tyler Cowen, titled “The Public Choice Theory of John C. Calhoun.”
Tabarrok and Cowen, who teach in the notoriously libertarian economics
department at George Mason University, argued that the fire-breathing South
Carolinian defender of slaveholders’ rights had anticipated “public choice
theory,” the sine qua non of modern libertarian political
thought.
That obscure academic journal is The Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. While it
may not be The Baffler, it has been
around for over 150 years, and Nobel prize winners, such as Oliver Williamson,
Douglass North and Ronald Coase have published in it.
Public choice theory,
which grew in stature across the late twentieth century and is now a bedrock
conservative doctrine marketed to right-wing policymakers by the billionaire
Koch brothers, has indeed tilted the scales of justice in favor of the white,
rich, and powerful.
Libertarians seem unaware that Buchanan’s public choice
theory is the thing without which their philosophy cannot exist. Milton
Friedman does not refer to Buchanan or public choice in Capitalism
and Freedom. Robert Nozick does not mention Buchanan or public choice in Anarchy,
State and Utopia. David Boaz can put
together a 600 page Libertarian
Reader that has just a handful of references to public choice and no
readings from Buchanan or Tullock. On a personal note, I was once invited to a
lunch where John Allison former head of BB&T and a well-known libertarian
spoke. I remember him talking a lot about Aristotle, but I don’t recall any mention
of Buchanan or any other public choice theorists. I’m not suggesting that there
are not libertarians who like Buchanan’s work, but I don’t see a case for the
claim that it is regarded as an essential ingredient.
In marking Calhoun’s
political philosophy as the crucial antecedent of public choice theory,
Tabarrok and Cowen unwittingly confirmed what critics have long maintained:
libertarianism is a political philosophy shot through with white supremacy.
Public choice theory, a technical language nominally about human behavior and
incentives, helps ensure that blacks remain shackled.
Cowen and Tabarok did not mark Calhoun as a crucial
antecedent of public choice. To the contrary, they argue that economists have
ignored Calhoun. It would be more accurate to say that they argue that although
Calhoun did not influence the development of public choice theory, there are
some interesting similarities. They note some of these similarities, but also
point to significant differences. Including the differences that enabled him to
include support for slavery in his philosophy.
The sheer volume and
intensity of these protests suggest that MacLean’s observations have hit a
nerve. And by historicizing the putatively neutral and scientific character of
Buchanan’s research, MacLean has apparently shaken the pediment supporting the
altar of this libertarian saint.
Apparently, Hartman regards it as noteworthy that calling
someone’s friend a racist would strike a nerve. I’m not sure what to make of
that. As for neutral. I don’t know of anyone who would argue that Buchanan’s
work was neutral. Buchanan had values that he argued for throughout his career.
There is just no evidence that racism was one of them.
Just as Calhoun
developed his novel political philosophy in response to the growing fear among
his class of southern slaveholders that a Northern majority might seek to
abolish slavery, Buchanan’s public choice theory was an innovative approach to
resisting federal enforcement of civil rights in the South.
Hartman simply parrots MacLean here. They use innuendo to
create a link between Buchanan and segregation, while ignoring the well
documented intellectual context in which Buchanan was working. Buchanan was one
of a number of people in the 1950s and 1960s working on applying economic or
rational choice methods to the analysis of politics.
Buchanan saw his work as part of this broader movement. The
following quotes are from a talk
he gave on public choice theory at Hillsdale College in 2003
“Public choice should be understood as a research program
rather than a discipline or even a subdiscipline of economics. Its origins date
to the mid-20th century, and viewed retrospectively, the theoretical “gap” in
political economy that it emerged to fill seems so large that its development
seems to have been inevitable. Nations emerging from World War II, including
the Western democracies, were allocating between one-third and one-half of
their total product through political institutions rather than through markets.
Economists, however, were devoting their efforts almost exclusively to
understanding and explaining the market sector.” He goes on to explain that he “entered
this discussion with a generalized critique of the analysis generated by the
Arrow Black approach.” He also describes the 19th century thinker
who influenced his work. No, it was not Calhoun. It was Knut Wicksell.
Oddly, Hartman cites S.M.
Amadae, but seems to have missed Amadae’s description of this broader
context, Amadae describes Buchanan’s early essays as responses to the work of
Ken Arrow and his Calculus of Consent
(with Gordon Tullock) as “a new analysis of the rapidly forming study of
politics that had been articulated by John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern,
Duncan Black, Arrow, and Arrow’s student Anthony Downs.” (Amadae 136)
Buchanan was part of a movement to develop a rational choice
approach to politics. He also had normative views about what government should
do. These beliefs were essential to James Buchanan, but not central to public
choice. Being interested in a rational
choice approach to politics does not require that one hold any specific set of
normative beliefs. A rational choice approach to politics has been followed by
people as disparate views of what should be as James Buchanan, Amartya Sen,
Howard Rosenthal and Jon Elster.
Other people involved in the development of a rational
choice approach to politics, such as Anthony
Downs, Amartya
Sen and Mancur
Olson, also viewed Buchanan’s work as part of this broader movement and
engaged his arguments in their work.
If Hartman is right, then he and MacLean have seen through a
false facade that fooled all of these other scholars. Buchanan somehow managed
to hide his true motives from all of them, tricking them into believing that,
like them, he was trying to understand
collective decision making, when in fact he was simply working to preserve race
based segregation.
As opposed to wishing
to free the masses from a state controlled by the capitalist elite, Buchanan wished
to free the capitalist elite from a state controlled by the unruly masses. And
this returns us, suitably enough, to John C. Calhoun.
Public choice theory is interesting and important because recognizing
that the state is composed of human beings means that the state can be
controlled by an elite that oppresses the masses or a majority that oppresses a
minority. The outcome depends upon the
institutions for making public choices. Some of us hope that it is possible to
have institutional arrangements that protect the majority from a despotic elite
and protect minorities from the tyranny of the majority.
In the end, there is no evidence for Hartman’s argument and
considerable evidence against it. Public choice theory did not develop out of
the work of Calhoun nor was it an outgrowth of attempts to preserve segregation
in Virginia. Buchanan was influential in the development of public choice, but public
choice theory is not synonymous with the thought of James Buchanan. Buchanan and public choice theory are not the
sine qua non of modern libertarianism. In fact there is no necessary connection
between public choice and any set of normative beliefs.
In the end, I am puzzled why Hartman would choose to write
an essay about something that he obviously has so little interest in? He doesn’t
appear to have made any attempt to learn anything about the history of public
choice theory beyond reading MacLean. He
could have written a better informed essay if he had read the Wikipedia page on
public choice.
Wednesday, November 15, 2017
Some Recent Podcasts
If you are interested in the economy of colonial America
listen to two recent episodes of Liz Covart’s Ben Franklin’s World: The Revolutionary Economy and The Politics of Tea. Of course, the politics of tea is
about the economics of tea.
If you want to know about the economic divergence between
Western Europe and the Middle East listen to Jared Rubin discuss his recent
book on Garreth Petersen’s Economics
Detective.
If, on the other hand, you are interested in listening to
two intellectual historians who do not know anything about public
choice theory discuss a book about public choice theory by another intellectual
historian who does not know anything about public choice theory you should definitely
check out Andrew Hartman and Ray Haberski discussing Nancy McLean’s Democracy
in Chains on
Trotsky and the Wild Orchids
Monday, November 13, 2017
New Books in Economic and Business History
The Business History Conference's blog The Exchange has a list of new and forthcoming books in economic and business history. There are several that I am looking forward to reading
Anne Fleming, City of Debtors: A Century of Fringe Finance (Harvard University Press, December 2017)
Douglas A. Irwin, Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade Policy (University of Chicago Press, November 2017)
Naomi R. Lamoreaux and John Joseph Wallis, eds., Organizations, Civil Society, and the Roots of Development(University of Chicago Press, December 2017)
Qian Lu, From Partisan Banking to Open Access: The Emergence of Free Banking in Early Nineteenth Century Massachusetts (Palgrave, October 2017)
Laura Philips Sawyer, American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the 'New Competition,' 1890–1940(Cambridge University Press, December 2017)
Anne Fleming, City of Debtors: A Century of Fringe Finance (Harvard University Press, December 2017)
Douglas A. Irwin, Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade Policy (University of Chicago Press, November 2017)
Naomi R. Lamoreaux and John Joseph Wallis, eds., Organizations, Civil Society, and the Roots of Development(University of Chicago Press, December 2017)
Qian Lu, From Partisan Banking to Open Access: The Emergence of Free Banking in Early Nineteenth Century Massachusetts (Palgrave, October 2017)
Laura Philips Sawyer, American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the 'New Competition,' 1890–1940(Cambridge University Press, December 2017)
Thursday, October 26, 2017
Business History's Introspective Mood
Business history appears to be in an introspective mood.
Business
History Review has a special issue on debating methodology in business
history.
The latest issue of Business History
examines the role of narrative in business history.
In First View at Enterprise
and Society you can find Water Friedman’s talk “Recent Trends in Business History:
Capitalism, Democracy, and Innovation” from the meeting of the Business
History Conference.
In general, business history seems to be an unusually
introspective field.
The introduction to the special issue of Business History Review,
for instance, provides this list of recent work on methodology in business
history:
“Recent examples
include Naomi R. Lamoreaux, “Reframing the Past: Thoughts about Business
Leadership and Decision Making under Uncertainty,” Enterprise & Society 2,
no. 4 (2001): 632–59; Mary O’Sullivan and Margaret B. W. Graham, “Moving
Forward by Looking Backward: Business History and Management Studies,” Journal
of Management Studies 47, no. 5 (2010): 775–90; Geoffrey Jones and Walter A.
Friedman, “Business History: Time for Debate,” Business History Review 85, no. 1
(2011): 1–8; Daniel M. G. Raff, “How to Do Things with Time,” Enterprise &
Society 14, no. 3 (2013): 435–66; Matthias Kipping and Behlül Ãœsdiken, “History
and Organization Studies: A Long-Term View,” in Organizations in Time: History,
Theory, Methods, ed. Marcelo Bucheli and R. Daniel Wadhwani (New York, 2014),
33–55; Abe de Jong, David Michael Higgins, and Hugo van Driel, “Towards a New
Business History?” Business History 57, no. 1 (2015): 5–29; Stephanie Decker,
Matthias Kipping, and Daniel Wadhwani, “New Business Histories! Plurality in
Business History Research Methods,” Business History 57, no. 1 (2015): 30–40;
and Christina Lubinski and Daniel Wadhwani, “Reinventing Entrepreneurial
History,” Business History Review (forthcoming).”
Monday, September 25, 2017
New History of Capitalism meets the History of Economic Thought
Jonathan Levy has a paper forthcoming in Business History Review, “Capital
as Process and the History of Capitalism.” If you have access to the
journal it is available on First View. He attempts to develop a definition of
capital that is useful for the study of capitalism. I should be grading papers
right now so I will make this quick.
Unfortunately, it bears many of the hallmarks of some of
the most celebrated work in the new history of capitalism.
1. Misunderstanding basic economics: Here for, for instance, is
his description of the problems associated with thinking of capital as a
produced means of production
And yet, because it
equates capital with a produced physical factor of production, the materialist
conception is a highly restrictive definition of capital. For the writing of
history, there are chiefly three almost natural consequences of the materialist
restriction. First, because of its emphasis on a produced factor of physical
production, capital becomes almost synonymous with industrial machinery and
equipment. Second, likewise the materialist capital concept abstracts from
money—treating monetary and financial dynamics as extrinsic to both capital and
the “real economy” in general. Third, for reasons to be explained later, the materialist
capital concept is a temporally static concept. Thus, in addition to money it
also abstracts from historical time—or at least, in pursuit of analytical
clarity, it abstracts from the many eventful historical processes that are
extrinsic from the point of view of the physical characteristics of the masses
of objects that materialists define as capital.
Reference to a principles of economics textbook would have
made clear that capital is not synonymous with industrial machinery and
equipment.
2. Use of sources that can at best be described as sloppy. I
have been interested in Veblen since I was an undergraduate. Levy seems
interested in Veblen as well. When I checked the places where
Levy specifically quotes Veblen this is what I found. Levy is in bold
“At the most abstract
level, capital, in this line of thought, is what Thorstein Veblen once called a
“pecuniary magnet.”11 (Levy page 5)
“11
Thorstein B. Veblen, “On the Nature of Capital II: Investment, Intangible
Assets, and the
Pecuniary Magnate,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 23, no. 1
(1908): 104–36.”
One might think that Veblen used the phrase “pecuniary
magnet” in this paper. He did not. He did use the phrase “pecuniary magnate.”
But a magnate is not a magnet. Veblen is referring to people, “captains of
industry,” not capital. If Veblen ever referred to capital as a pecuniary
magnet it was not in the cited paper.
Oddly enough, Berch Berberoglu made this same mistake earlier this year. Since neither references the other one has to conclude that they made the mistake independently.
“By becoming the
exclusive legal owners of capitalized goods, capitalists over time had
politically and legally “cornered” the market in immaterial “technological
expedients.”42” (Levy page 14)
“42 Thorstein B. Veblen, “Fisher’s Capital and Income,” Political
Science Quarterly 23, no. 1 (1908): 117.”
Again, one might think that the quoted phrases appear on page 117; they do not. Like “pecuniary magnet” they do not appear anywhere in the
paper.
“Addressing culture, Veblen argued that
capital was merely one economic “method of
doing things” in the
world among others.44” (Levy page 14)
“44 Thorstein
B. Veblen, “Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 12, no. 4 (1898): 389.”
Levy is at least in the ballpark this time. Veblen uses the
phrase “methods of doing things.” He does not, however, use it on page 389.
Page 389 is devoted to his critique of the hedonistic conception of man, not an
argument that capital was merely one economic method of doing things.
“If capital has no fixed,
authentic value, the question becomes, as Veblen put it, “Whose imputation of
value is to be accepted?”71 (Levy page 20)
“71 Veblen,
“Fisher’s Capital and Income,” 120.”
This time Levy almost nailed it. The quote is in the paper,
and he only missed the citation by 5 pages; its on page 125.
At what point does putting quotation marks around things
that were not a actually said by the person they are attributed to become a
problem in historical scholarship.
Sunday, September 3, 2017
I Blame Foner
The author in New York Times
By
the Book today was Jesmyn Ward, author of Sing, Unburied, Sing and Salvage
the Bones
These are her answers to two of the questions:
What’s the last great book you read?
“The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of
America Capitalism,” by Edward E. Baptist. It taught me so much about slavery
and how slavery enabled America to become America. Every time I left my house
after reading it, I saw the world differently. I saw the legacy of human misery
underpinning it all.
What’s the most interesting thing you learned from a book
recently?
From “The Half Has Never Been Told”: “All told, more than
$600 million, or almost half of the economic activity in the United States in
1836, derived directly or indirectly from cotton produced by the million-odd
slaves — 6 percent of the total U.S. population — who in that year toiled in
labor camps on slavery’s frontier.”
In other words, the most interesting thing she has learned
from a book recently is an inaccurate assessment of the role of slavery in the American
economy that was
concocted in Ed Baptist’s imagination and presented in one of the worst
books by an academic historian that I have ever read.
I blame Eric Foner. Foner is not the only one to blame, but
he certainly deserves a large share of the blame.
Foner praised the book in The New York Times and did not point out that Baptist
was simply making things up. Foner is a famous historian with a long record of
impressive scholarship. It is not unreasonable for non-historians to place
their faith in his assessments of work in American history. We all count on
recognized experts to give us some guidance in areas that are beyond our
personal expertise. Foner, however, failed them. He took a shot at economists,
repeated Baptist’s misleading historiography, and failed to note the
fundamental flaws in the book.
The flaws truly are fundamental. The claim that slavery was
the driving force behind American economic development was central to Baptist’s
book. I have seen the book cited on this point by numerous people. Yet Baptist
did not actually estimate the importance of slavery; he did not even try. He
made a up some numbers, added them up and compared them to an actual estimate of GDP.
The way he added up the numbers did not make sense. He is clearly unfamiliar with
the problem of double counting or the difference between the sales of newly
produced goods and the sales of assets. Even if he had looked in a principles of
economics textbook to learn the basics of national income accounting, however, it would not have solved the fundamental problem: he was just making up the numbers. Non-historians
are likely say to themselves, “These numbers must be okay; it was reviewed by famous
historians, like Eric Foner, and they did not say anything.” Eric Foner, however, does not have that
excuse. Nor do other historians who refused to call bullshit on Baptist. Foner
owed the readers of the New York Times
a critical reading of the book, and he let them down. Personally, I think this
unwillingness to call bullshit on other historians, just because you like their
conclusions, is a serious threat to the integrity of history.
As for me, as long as people keep citing his book, I will
keep pointing out that Baptist is a charlatan.
Friday, September 1, 2017
Economic History to Read, Listen and Watch
Read:
Victoria Bateman on Why
bigger states are more progressive
Listen:
Gregory Clark on Rationally
Speaking on What
Caused the Industrial Revolution? (and the why it is so difficult to answer
that question)
Noel Johnson at the Economics
Detective on The
French Revolution, Property Rights and the Coase Theorem
Watch:
Alan Taylor on credit
booms and crises in economic history
Deirdre McCloskey on How we got rich
Tuesday, August 22, 2017
Business History and the Great Divergence
Luca Zan and Kent Deng “Micro Foundations in the
Great Divergence Debate: Opening Up a New Perspective” LSE Department of
Economic History Working Paper No. 256 Jan. 2017
Abstract
Prevailing approaches in historical studies adopt a macro
view and place an overwhelming emphasis on the Industrial Revolution as a major
discontinuity in Western development. On the contrary, recent research in
accounting, management and business history has suggested a different
direction. When opting for a micro-level focus, crucial discontinuities in
management and accounting in the West can be traced back to the Renaissance
Period. The paper thus searches for ‘micro foundations’ in managing and
accounting practices to address the on-going debate on the East-West
divergence. Despite the obvious problems with source availability, we outline a
new research agenda for the debate.
Geoffrey Jones Business
History, the Great Divergence and the Great Convergence Harvard Business
School Working Paper 18-004
Abstract
This working paper provides a business history perspective
on debates about the Great Divergence, the rise of the income gap between the
West and the Rest, and the more recent Great Convergence, which has seen a
narrowing of that gap. The literature on the timing and causes of the Great
Divergence has focused on macro analysis. This working paper identifies the
potential for more engagement at the micro level of business enterprises. While
recognizing that the context of institutions, education, and culture plays a
role in explanations of wealth and poverty, the paper calls for a closer
engagement with the processes of how these factors translated into generating
productive firms and entrepreneurs. The challenges of catching up were
sufficiently great in the Rest that initially ethnic and religious minorities
held significant advantages in raising capital and trust levels, which enabled
them to flourish as entrepreneurs. Yet by the interwar years, there is evidence
of a more general emergence of modern business enterprise in Asia, Latin
America, and Africa. Many governmental policies after 1945 designed to
facilitate catch-up ended up crippling such emergent business enterprises
without putting effective alternatives in place. The second wave of
globalization from the 1980s provided more opportunities for catch-up from the
Rest. Firms from emerging markets had the opportunity to access the global
networks that replaced large integrated firms. There were also new ways to
access knowledge and capital, including through management consultancies and
hiring graduates from business schools. The upshot was the rise to global
prominence of firms based in the Rest, including Foxcomm, Huawei, HNA, Cemex,
and TCS.
Tuesday, August 15, 2017
Steinbaum on Public Choice
Marshall Steinbaum has published a
sort of review of NancyMacLean's Democracy in Chains in
which describes “the racist origins of Public Choice theory” and suggests
that everyone should read Democracy in Chains “despite its rhetorical
shortcomings.”
Steinbaum seems to unquestioningly accept MacLean’s claim that
Buchanan’s “study of how government officials make decisions became “public
choice economics.”” (MacLean xxiii) In making public choice theory and
Buchanan's though synonymous, Steinbaum and MacLean strip public choice of all
context other than that related to Buchanan. Buchanan, however, was only one of
a number of people attempting to apply economic methods (rational choice and
models) to the analysis of both politics and political philosophy. Duncan
Black’s work was published before Buchanan, and Ken Arrow, William Riker,
Vincent Ostrom, Amartya Sen and others were working on this approach in the 1950s and 1960s at the
same time as Buchanan. To the best of my knowledge, none of them appear
in Democracy in Chains. They are not listed in the index. The point is that there were a lot of people interested in applying
the economic approach to politics. Many of them did not have the same normative
preferences as Buchanan. It is this broader approach to public choice that
you will find in Mueller’s
text on the subject. It is even what you will find here at the Library
of Economics and Liberty. Public choice is more than James Buchanan.
By the way, this is more of a defense of public choice
theory than it is of Buchanan,Virginia, or UVA. The University of Virginia was
an avowedly racist and sexist place in the '50s and '60s? UVA was both all
white and all male (until the 1970s). To the best of my knowledge neither
Buchanan or anyone of his colleagues at the time made any effort to change
that. Of course that could be said of most of the men at UVA and a lot of other
universities at the time. The liberty they were most concerned with seemed to
be the liberty of men like themselves.
I'll also say that I have no intention of reading the whole
book. If you want to say I have no right to criticize it until I have read the
whole thing, go ahead. I don’t care. I don’t have enough time to waste on
historians that I do not trust. This is particularly true for a subject that I
do not regard as my area of expertise. If it is nineteenth or early twentieth
century American economic history I can quickly identify inconsistencies and
errors, but for other topics I need to have some faith in the historian. For me
the bottom line on MacLean’s book is still that there are numerous instances
where she did not honestly represent her sources. Misrepresenting your sources
is more than a rhetorical shortcoming.
Tuesday, August 8, 2017
Trust Company Failures and Institutional Change in New York, 1875-1925
My paper "Trust Company Failures and Institutional Change in New York, 1875-1925" is now available under First View at Enterprise and Society.
Here are the first two paragraphs
Here are the first two paragraphs
The State of New York created the
first trust company in 1822, when
it granted a corporate charter to
the Farmers’ Fire Insurance and
Loan Company, later renamed
Farmers’ Loan and Trust Company,
and authorized it to act as a
trustee. As the name suggests, Farmers
and other early trust companies,
like the New York Life Insurance
and Trust Company and the
Massachusetts Hospital Life Insurance
Company, also sold insurance, and
they provided trusts as an alternative
to insurance. Trust companies
later used their trust powers
to facilitate the development of
corporate finance by serving as registrars
and transfer agents for corporate
securities and as trustees for
corporate mortgages. Trust
companies also accepted deposits; by the
middle of the nineteenth century,
some of these deposits could be withdrawn
on demand including by check.
Thus, by the late nineteenth
century, trust companies in New
York occupied a unique position in
the financial system by combining
functions associated with banks
with functions associated with
trustees.
Between 1875 and 1925, the number
of trust companies in New York
State increased from ten to 110,
and the total resources of trust companies
increased more rapidly than those
of state banks or savings
banks. Trust companies have been
characterized as early examples
of “shadow banks,” operating
outside the laws and regulations that
applied to commercial banks. However,
as with other financial institutions,
New York State trust companies
rarely failed. Between 1875
and 1925, the superintendent of
banks only intervened eleven times
to deal with troubled trust
companies, and in several of these cases
the trust company reopened.
Despite this rarity, these failures provide
a path to understanding the
overall success of trust companies.
The path leads through
institutions: failures played a leading role in
shaping the institutions that
governed trust companies. Consequently,
failures shaped the expectations
and actions of everyone involved
with trust companies: depositors,
shareholders, and executives.
Friday, July 28, 2017
Some recent history and economic history
The latest issue of History Now from the Gilder
Lehrman Institute is about the history of the blues and jazz. It has this nice
list of links to music.
There has been a lot of discussion recently about
state capacity and the evolution of norms. I think it is safe to say many
economist historians regard both as essential to understanding long run
economic performance.
On state capacity, here is Koyama on Salter on Johnson and Koyama. And here is Koyama on Political Decentralization and Innovation
in early modern Europe and The Economist covers the work of
Anderson, Johnson and Koyama on poor harvests and violence.
On the evolution of norms:
Pseudoerasmus “Where Do Pro-Social Institutions Come
From?” originally published as a blog post but recently published on Evonomics.
Peter Turchin writes that
“Cultural
Evolution is a new interdisciplinary field whose intellectual roots go back
only to the 1970s (unless, of course, you count Charles Darwin; but in a sense
any new development in evolutionary science can be traced to Darwin). In this
new field, “culture” is defined as information, which can affect human
behavior, that is socially transmitted—through books and manuals, by teaching,
or simply by observing and imitation. Cultural variants are information packages
that cause people to behave in alternative ways. Cultural Evolution, then,
studies how and why frequencies of cultural variants change with time, just as
biological evolution focuses on the changing frequencies of genetic variants.”
Of course North placed a great deal of
emphasis on the importance of changing beliefs (especially in Structure and Change
and later works) but this also reminds me of Veblen, who argued that “institutions
are, in substance, prevalent habits of thought with respect to particular
relations and to particular functions of the individual and of the community” and
that "the evolution of society is substantially a process of mental
adaption on the part of individuals under the stress of circumstances which
will no longer tolerate habits of thought formed under and conforming to
circumstances in the past." He argued that these prevalent habits of
thoughts influenced both the objectives that people sought to achieve and the
means that they perceived to achieve them. Consequently, their evolution should
be the primary concern of economists.
In addition, Jared Rubin and Murat Iyigun
have a paper on the Ideological Roots of Institutional Change
BTW there is actually a connection between the first link and the last link in this post.
Monday, July 17, 2017
The Importance of Honesty in Historical Research
I am not now, nor have I ever been a
fellow at the Mercatus Institute or any other institute that receives funding
from the Koch brothers. I have never received any funding from the Koch
brothers. To be honest, I haven’t received much funding from anyone else either.
I know several people at Mercatus (Mark Koyama, Noel Johnson, and John Nye),
and I have been there a couple of times when the Washington Area Economic
History Seminar was held there. I am not a libertarian, I have, in fact,
written several blog posts critical of libertarians generally as well as
specific people affiliated with Mercatus: Walter
Williams, Arnold
Kling, Bryan
Caplan and Tyler Cowen. Finally, I never met James Buchanan and if I have
ever cited him I can’t think of where it would be. I hope this establishes my
bona fides as not just another shill for the Koch brothers.
Now that I have gotten that out of
the way, I find the arguments that some historians are making in support of
Nancy MacLean’s Democracy in Chains mindboggling.
MacLean quoting Cowen: “the weakening of checks and balances
would increase the chance of a very good outcome.”
Cowen’s full quote: “While the weakening of checks and
balances would increase the chance of a very good outcome, it also would
increase the chance of a very bad outcome.”
This is scholarly malpractice. Are
there really professors who would accept this from a student? It is indefensible,
yet Andy
Seal defends it:
This is the document in
question, “Why Does Freedom Wax and Wane?” although there is also a second
version available on-line here. (That
becomes somewhat important, as you’ll see in a moment.) The crucial
sentence in question is—in full—the following: “While
the weakening of checks and balances would increase the chance of a very good
outcome, it also would increase the chance of a very bad outcome.” When
MacLean quoted this sentence, she left out the “While” and the “it also would
increase the chance of a very bad outcome.” Thus, in her book it appears as “the
weakening of checks and balances would increase the chance of a very good
outcome.”
Her critics see this as prima facie evidence of a bad faith effort to distort
Cowen’s meaning to make him appear to be anti-democratic. I think that’s
immediately debatable, however, because by her
lights any open-minded contemplation of the possibility of
weakening checks and balances is anti-democratic. And
that’s what Cowen is doing here: entertaining the possibility that weakening
checks and balances could produce a desirable outcome.
Let’s think about it this way. If I said,
“While permitting five-year-olds to be employed in manual labor would increase
the chance of a very good outcome, it also would increase the chance of a very
bad outcome,” what could we conclude? That I was advocating child labor?
No, that would be too much. But that I was open to the idea? Yes, that’s a fair
reading of the sentence.
He claims that her version of the quote does not show bad
faith “because by her lights any open-minded
contemplation of the possibility of weakening checks and balances is anti-democratic.”
But consider Seals’s example: “While
permitting five-year-olds to be employed in manual
labor would increase the chance of a very good outcome, it also would
increase the chance of a very bad outcome.” Who believes that it would be
acceptable to quote him as saying: “permitting
five-year-olds to be employed in manual labor would increase the chance of a
very good outcome”? What if I told you that it is okay because in my lights
any open-minded contemplation of the possibility of child labor is supportive
of child labor? Would it be okay then?
This is not a small matter. I can’t
just brush this issue aside and look at her broader argument because I can't trust somone who does this. Her claims may very well be correct, but I am not going to be
persuaded by her argument because I can’t trust the evidence that she puts forward
in favor of them. I don’t care what a historian’s political leanings are, I need
to be able to trust that they are honestly representing their sources.
Friday, July 7, 2017
Internet Videos and Economic History
I frequently post videos related to economic history,
usually recordings of presentations at seminars or conferences. For the most
part I like being a professor at a liberal arts college, but I must admit I do
miss the seminars of a research university. There were economic history and
political economy seminars every week at Washington University when I was there.
Now I even find it difficult to get to the Washington Area Economic History
Seminar, which takes place once a month. Consequently, I really appreciate it
when people record and post such presentations.
There is another kind of economic history video: videos that
are meant specifically for instruction. Some of these simply record the
lectures that are presented in a regular economic history course. Two of these
that are pretty good are Greg Clark’s World
Economic History and Martha Olney’s
American Economic History.
There is yet another category of videos: videos created
which present interpretations of economic history created specifically for the
internet. I have looked at two such series recently. Unfortunately both have serious
problems of content and style.
One series is the videos associated with the EdX course on
the history of capitalism created by Edward Baptist and Louis Hyman the other
is a series of short videos presented at learnliberty.org.
Not surprisingly, the history of capitalism one is bar far
the worse. Thanks to these videos anyone with an internet connection can be misinformed
by Baptist for free. Take for instance his analysis of the Panic of 1837
in this video. There are so many things wrong with his presentation that I
plan to do a later post specifically about the Panic of 1837, but for now just
listen to the part that starts about 52 seconds in. He suggests that increases
in cotton output caused cotton prices to fall (be early 1836 they were creeping
down) and that this made cotton textile producers in England nervous. What? That’s
right cotton textile producers were nervous because the costs of production
were falling. If you are thinking that makes no sense, you are right. Not only
does this story not make sense it is factually incorrect. Cotton prices did not
start creeping down in early 1836; they were going up. Prices in New Orleans
remained over 14 cents a pound into early 1837. See Gray, Lewis Cecil.
"History of Agriculture in the Southern United States to 1860, 2 vols.,
New York, 1941, Vol. 2 page 1027 or the price data available here at the
Center for International Price Research.) Prices plunged after the Panic, but
that doesn’t fit Baptist’s story. Baptist wants overproduction of cotton to
have caused the Panic.
Like Foghorn Leghorn, Baptist says “Don’t’ talk to me about
facts, son. I’ve already made up my mind.” As I mentioned earlier I’ll deal
with the rest of this story of the Panic later. In his book Baptist claimed
that slaves accounted for 1/5th of the nation’s wealth; in the video
on Northern and Southern Capitalism he ups it to 1/3 and adds the phrase “by
law,” as if there were a law declaring the percentage of wealth that would be
attributed of the value of slaves. In the video on Incentives and Slavery he again
claims that enslaved people used the phrase “pushing system.” But the estimates
about wealth are unfounded and the phrase pushing system was invented by Ed
Baptist, not enslaved people. (Please search scholar.google.com for papers by
Olmstead and Rhode on the New History of Capitalism.)
The problem with the Learn Liberty videos is more a problem
of emphasis. For instance, in the video on the
Civil War it states that slavery was the cause of the War but spends 4 of
the 5 minutes talking about tariffs and internal improvements. The video on the
Great Depression doesn’t talk about the role of the gold standard. It really
has too much some people think this and other people think that without any attempt
to evaluate what they think, as if all opinions are equally valid.
Of course, the videos
of seminar presentations that I like also do not provide all of the
documentation of a book or paper, but they are directed at an audience of
people that have expertise on the subject. Such an audience will be much more
likely to detect obvious bullshit like Baptist’s.
I said that there were problems with both content and style.
The problem with the style is that they do not make good use of the
visual medium. They are primarily one person talking to a camera. Baptist and
Hyman do, however, have a lot of books behind them: I guess they must know what
they are talking about. The Learn Liberty videos make some use of visuals, but
it is more eye candy to keep your attention than actual information. How some
graphs, maps, and tables. If you are going to go the trouble to produce a video
about economic history show us a how a spinning wheel and a spinning jenny worked.
Show us reaping by hand
and a mechanical reaper. Show
us what it is like to pick
cotton, and how a cotton gin worked. I’ve never understood how someone can
have a real sense of the industrial revolution without seeing some of these
things. As they exist now these talking to the camera videos are far inferior to books which provide more illustrations and documentation or good podcasts, which provide interaction between author and interviewer.
Sunday, June 25, 2017
Nebraska, The Good Life
We spent the last week in Kearney, NE visiting family. Kearney
is easy to find; it is at the bottom of where the Platte dips south.
My parents
were both from Nebraska. We lived in south central Nebraska until we moved to
San Francisco when I was 10. My brother moved back after high school and my
parents moved back after my dad retired from the Coast Guard. I know many people consider Nebraska to be the
middle of nowhere, which would make Kearney the middle of the middle of nowhere,
but it is actually a great place to visit for anyone interested in American
history.
This week Mary and I went to the Stuhr Museum of the Prairie Pioneer in
Grand Island. I hadn’t been there since I was a kid. Some things I learned on
this trip
1.
The first African American to play football at
the University of Nebraska, George
Flippin was the son of a former slave who had become a physician. George
Flippin also became a physician and founded the first hospital in Stromsburg,
NE.
2.
The first “successful” sugar
beet processing plant in the U.S. was established in Grand Island in 1889.
Here
is a video that will give you an idea of how much there is to see at the
Stuhr Museum.
If you are in the area you can also go about ten miles south
of I 80 to Minden, NE and see Pioneer
Village. Here is a video
that gives a small sample of the things you can see at Pioneer Village.
If you are traveling through Nebraska either museum is worth
the detour.
If you are interested in the history of the Great Plains they are
worth a trip.
P.S. the "Kear" in Kearney is pronounced like "car."
P.S. the "Kear" in Kearney is pronounced like "car."
The Golden Age of Economic History?
At Marginal
Revolution Tyler Cowen responded to a reader:
C. inquires:
Why do we live in the
golden age of economic history? Was there something identifiable that caused
the subfield to grow in esteem? Some new technology that changed the costs of
research (not that I can see)? Something else?
Mark Koyama should
write a Medium essay on this, but in the meantime here are my thoughts:
1. We now know much,
much more about the earlier economic
histories of China, India, and
some other locales. The rise of more and better graduate students from
the emerging economies, or for that matter from Europe, has been essential
here.
2. Some of the turn
toward economic history came with the financial crisis, and the search for
longer-term parallels, which meant looking back in history, most of all to the
Great Depression.
3. Although the
advance of cliometrics started a long time ago, we are now finally at intergenerational
margins where economic historians are as quantitatively well-equipped as most
parts of the applied micro spectrum.
4. The stranger the
time period, the more people will have to look to broader stretches of history
for understanding. Yes, this one is an uh-oh.
5. Some applied micro
fields have become a little more boring, so that has helped a partial shift of
status to economic history. Public data sets have been exhausted, and a
lot of economic history data sets are “weird or idiosyncratic” data sets, which
now are “in” and I predict will stay “in” for a long while to come because they
offer the possibilities of both new discoveries and moats.
6. An academic trend
that hasn’t yet been exploited usually ends up exploited, sooner or later, once
the right nudge comes along.
5b, 6b. In chess, the
top players are opting for the Giuoco Piano once again.
7. Competing economic
models are more “allowed” in the subfield — not everything must be neoclassical
— which has opened economic historians to more wide-ranging questions.
Economic history remains a good place to pursue the questions about economics
that initially interested many people as undergraduates.
8. Academic attention
is more media-driven these days, and good economic history papers usually have
a story of some kind, and perhaps also a historical personage, event, or
institution of broader interest.
The post prompted a lot of discussion on Twitter. My initial
response to the question is
1.
While I often argue that economic history is
doing very well, I’m not sure that this is the golden age. There is a lot of great work going on in economic history. Economic
historians are doing well at publishing in top journals, and many of the top
econ programs have strong fields in economic history. On the other hand, there
are still not a lot of economic history jobs in JOE. The problem with a golden
age is that it seems to imply that this is as good as it gets. I would still like to see more jobs
in economic history, more students studying economic history, and a wider
audience for good economic history. I would like for economic history to be more widely regarded as central to the study of economics. At the very least, I would like to see Washington University, where I studied with Doug North and John Nye, have economic history as a field again.
2.
I think there has been an important
technological change: the ability to take high quality digital photographs of
archival documents. This change has benefited history generally, but economic
history has probably benefited most. Archives used to be places where people
scribbled notes (with pencils). You were limited by how much time you could
afford to spend in the archive and how quickly you could scribble. Now,
archives are places where people take pictures, which can at relatively low
cost (thanks to software and the ability to offshore transcription) be converted
into text or data that you can analyze. Creating useable data sets from primary
sources is still difficult and time consuming, but less so than it used to be.
3.
I agree that the increase in the relative
importance of empirical work in economics has benefited economic history.
Donaldson’s Clark medal suggests a willingness to recognize good empirical work
regardless of the time or place it examines.
4.
There is a lot of interest in questions that
require us to look at history: long run growth, the productivity slow down,
inequality, racism, and financial crises. Of course, these things can and
should be analyzed with economic theory as well, but combined with the turn to
empirical analysis they present an opportunity for economic history.
5.
There has been an increase in popular interest
in economic history, but the work that has received the most attention (New
History of Capitalism) has often done more to misinform than to educate. I hope
an equivalent of Gresham’s law does not apply to economic history, but it
remains to be seen.