In the New York times, Raj Chetty discusses the Nobel winners and economics as a science. It is much better than this silly essay by Alex Rosenberg and Tyler Curtain, in which they argue that economics is not a science because it can't make predictions and then sugges that "an economic approach had much to contribute to the design and creative management of such institutions. Fixing bad economic and political institutions (concentrations of power, collusions and monopolies), improving good ones (like the Fed’s open-market operations), designing new ones (like electromagnetic bandwidth auctions), in the private and public sectors, are all attainable tasks of economic theory." How will economic theory help you to fix, improve or create institutions if it does not make predictions about the results of those changes?
This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, October 21, 2013
Tuesday, September 3, 2013
Ronald Coase
Coase passed away.
Thanks to Doug North and Lee Benham, I was fortunate to see
Ronald Coase in person on several occasions. I remember the first time someone
asked him about the appropriate size of government. He said that it was a bit
like the 400 pound man who asked his doctor how much he should way. The doctor responded
“Well, less.”
Monday, September 2, 2013
Internship Information
Think Tanks
The Cato Institute
The Brookings Institution
The American Enterprise Institute
The Heritage Foundation
The Urban Institute
Center for American Progress
The Cato Institute
The Brookings Institution
The American Enterprise Institute
The Heritage Foundation
The Urban Institute
Center for American Progress
The Tax Foundation
Government
Council of Economic Advisors
Bureau of Labor Statistics
The Bureau of Economic Analysis
Congressional Budget Office
Environmental Protection Agency
Federal Reserve Board
Federal Trade Commission
Business
BB &T
Geico
Government
Council of Economic Advisors
Bureau of Labor Statistics
The Bureau of Economic Analysis
Congressional Budget Office
Environmental Protection Agency
Federal Reserve Board
Federal Trade Commission
Business
BB &T
Geico
Booz Allen
Hamilton
Development
First People’s Worldwide
Development
First People’s Worldwide
Monday, August 26, 2013
Another Loss
This has been a rough couple of months for Economic History and American History. I posted earlier this summer abou the death of Bob Fogel. Shortly after that, Edmund Morgan, author of American Slavery American Freedom: the Ordeal of Colonial Virginia and numerous other works, passed away. In July, Cynthia Taft Morris died. Along with Irma Adelman, Cynthia was a pioneer in the effort to measure institutions and institutional change. Then Pauline Maier. Maier is probably best known for American Scripture: The Making of the Declaration of Independence, but her paper on "The Revolutionary Origins of the American Corporation," William and Mary Quarterly (1993) has been widely cited in American economic history. Today I read that David Landes has passed away.
Saturday, June 15, 2013
More New History of Capitalism (aka lets just make stuff up)
Since the NY Times article on the New History of Captalism, I have been trying to catch up with the recent work in this field. Unfortunately, I was dissapointed by Jonathan Levy's Freaks of Fortune. I just started Julia Ott's When Wall Street Met Main Street. On the first page of the first chapter she declares that "Severe financial panics in 1873 and 1893 punctuated a prolonged economic depression, as prices, profits, per capita output and productivity growth fell steadily from 1873 to 1896." She does not provide the source for this statement. Most of it is not true. Prices fell, but real output per capita increased. Overall, the period was one of relatively rapid productivity growth.
This is a graph of real gdp per capita during the period in question.
Source:www.measuringworth.com
Per capita output did not fall steadily; it rose unsteadily.
This information is not hard to find.
This is a graph of real gdp per capita during the period in question.
Source:www.measuringworth.com
Per capita output did not fall steadily; it rose unsteadily.
This information is not hard to find.
Wednesday, June 12, 2013
Friday, May 31, 2013
Wealth
The Washington Post has an article based on research at the St. Louis Fed, showing that net worth has not recovered from the recession. The article is titled Americans have rebuilt less than half the wealth lost to recession.
The article includes the following graph
Its not clear, however, that comparing wealth to the 2007 peak makes sense. Consider the following graph of net worth from 1990 to 2012
The two graphs are not directly comparable. The lower one shows net worth of all households and non-profit organizations in billions of dollars. It is not adjusted for inflation or the number of households. Nevertheless, it illustrates the problem with the first graph. The build up in wealth from 2002 to 2007 was clearly above the trend. why woulkd it be reasonable to expect a return to that lelvel of wealth rather than a return to the trend. The current levels of net worth appears consistent with the longer term trend.
The article includes the following graph
Its not clear, however, that comparing wealth to the 2007 peak makes sense. Consider the following graph of net worth from 1990 to 2012
The two graphs are not directly comparable. The lower one shows net worth of all households and non-profit organizations in billions of dollars. It is not adjusted for inflation or the number of households. Nevertheless, it illustrates the problem with the first graph. The build up in wealth from 2002 to 2007 was clearly above the trend. why woulkd it be reasonable to expect a return to that lelvel of wealth rather than a return to the trend. The current levels of net worth appears consistent with the longer term trend.
from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2 |
Monday, May 27, 2013
Shame on the OAH: A Rant About Joanthan Levy's Freaks of Fortune
The Organization of American Historians recently presented Jonathan
Levy’s Freaks of Fortune with book three
awards. If this is as good as it gets in American history, the field is in a
sad state. The book is not great history; it is not even good history.
The premise of the book is that the history of “risk” as we
know it dates to the nineteenth century. He explains that “at the end of the eighteenth
century “risk” still simply referred to a commodity bought and sold in an
insurance contract. Outside long distance maritime trade risk had very little
meaning or use.” And by the end of the
nineteenth century “risk was in fact everywhere. Before that century of capitalist
transformation, however, it was not.” Before this capitalist transformation risk
did not mean “extreme peril, hazard or danger.” But the capitalist system that “thrives
off radical uncertainty” brought “the insecurity of the sea to the land.” This
is all fascinating. Unfortunately, it is also nonsense. The first American
dictionary, Noah Webster’s 1806 Compendious
Dictionary of the English Language, was much less extensive than his later
works but still included the word risk:
Risk, n. hazard, chance, danger
Risk, v.t. to hazard, expose to chance, endanger
A quick search of American Periodical Series Online can
provide examples of the use of “risk” outside a maritime context:
In 1789 and essay in Columbian Magazine notes that allowing
hay to lie out for several days before it is collected”subjects it very much to
the danger of getting rain, and thus runs a great risk of being made good for
little.” (Columbian Magazine July
1789)
Or, “The inconveniences of ridges high and crooked are so
many, that one would be tempted to apply a remedy and any risk.” (Christian Scholar’s and Farmer’s Magazine
July 1789)
The whole book is based on a premise that is nonsense and
easily shown to be so. Moreover, accepting the premise requires one to ignore
considerable research about how people, especially farmers, dealt with risk before
the nineteenth century.
Levy goes onto talk about things like the Farmers’ Loan and Security Company, which did not
exist. He may at least have been close this time; there was a Farmer’s Loan and Trust Company. Perhaps this is nitpicking, but
how could someone study the history of capitalism and not know about the
Farmers’ Loan and Trust Company, one of the named parties in Pollock v. Farmers’
Loan and Trust Company, the 1895 case that ruled an income tax
unconstitutional.
I can’t say that there were not parts of the book that I
found interesting and enjoyable, but, overall, I found it to be deeply flawed.
It came nowhere near the standards that historians should aspire to. The members
of the OAH should be the ones most concerned that American history be based on
thorough, careful and critical consideration of the sources; they should
be the ones shouting that the emperor has no clothes when it is not. Instead, they have granted the emperor
three awards for the best robes.
Correction August 31. 2019 Mike Konczal pointed out to me that Levy referred to the Farmers' Loan and Trust Company as the Farmers' Loan and Security Trust Company not the Farmers' Loan and Security Company.
Correction August 31. 2019 Mike Konczal pointed out to me that Levy referred to the Farmers' Loan and Trust Company as the Farmers' Loan and Security Trust Company not the Farmers' Loan and Security Company.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)