This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Wednesday, February 25, 2015
Koyama on the History Manifesto
Mark Koyama reviews the History Manifesto. In it he mentions Pseudoerasmus' post on the many errors in the book.
Tuesday, February 24, 2015
The rise and fall of economic history
Peter Temin describes the rise and fall of economic history
at MIT in the History of
Political Economy and an un-gated version here.
Temin also talks about the costs of not
having actual economic historians, even if you do have people who write about
history.
MIT isn’t the only place to experience a rise and fall of
economic history. My grad school (for my econ Ph. D.) has pretty much completely turned its back on
economic history. When I was there we had Douglass North, John Nye, and, for
the last year or so, Sukoo Kim. There was a well-attended history lunch every
week. Doug retired. John went to George Mason. Soks is still there, but my
understanding is that he is not very involved in the economics department.
History is not listed as a field for graduate students. The economists that
replaced the economic historians have demonstrated the potential problems
associated with model makers using the past without consideration for the
historians concerns with context and source criticism. Boldrin and Levine use
the example of James Watt to argue against patents. On the actual influence of
Watt’s patent see Selgin and Turner “Strong
Steam, Weak Patents” JLE 2011 or Bottomley’s British
Patent system During the Industrial Revolution.
My wife’s grad school
also moved away from economic history. While she was doing her graduate work at
Illinois they had Jeremy Atack, Larry Neal, Lee Alston, and Charles Calomiris.
Now, if they have an economic historian, I don’t know who it is.
Fortunately, it is also possible to name departments where
economic history is either on the rise or holding its position, with multiple
economic historians and consistent production of good Ph. D. students. UC
Davis, Yale, Vanderbilt, George Mason, and Northwestern are some of the schools
that come to mind. My apologies to the other good schools I did not mention.
Sunday, February 22, 2015
Bankruptcy
Juan Sanchez of the St. Louis Fed looks at recent bankruptcies and concludes that
"BAPCPA clearly had an impact on the number of bankruptcies being filed. However, the exact impact may not be known for some time, since the recession hit right after the BAPCPA was implemented."
I agree that it is going to be difficult to determine the impact of BAPCPA (Bankruptcy Abuse and Consumer Protection Act) . Consumer bankruptcy is usually the end of a series of events: debt, default, and non-bankruptcy collection. There are a many things besides the bankruptcy law that play a role in the process.
Also from the St Louis Fed is this discussion of a symposium on the balance sheets of American families.
Friday, February 20, 2015
The Gold Standard
Here is my favorite gold standard political cartoon from an 1896 Harper's Weekly.
The cartoon shows godlbugs as widows, orphans and veterans. In other words, people living on fixed incomes. It reflects the view that the primary benefit of a gold standard was to place a constraint on the money supply.
However, from the St Louis Fed on U.S. economic performance under the gold standard from the St. Louis Fed: "the historical evidence indicates that neither a gold standard nor the absence of a central bank guarantees economic or financial stability."
Thursday, February 19, 2015
The end of capitalism?
Jeremy Rifkin says the end of
capitalism is coming. In the meantime, he will tell you about it for only $20,000 to $40,000.
History of Capitalism at the Legatum Institute
The Legatum Institute has a program on the History of Capitalism.
They are sponsoring a series of lectures, which are available online.
This one is Nicholas Crafts explaining why England was first to industrialize.
They are sponsoring a series of lectures, which are available online.
This one is Nicholas Crafts explaining why England was first to industrialize.
Wednesday, February 18, 2015
Bailyn, Wood and American History
I was a bit surprised when Wood suggested that historians
had not liked the Barbarous Years. I quickly looked at the reviews in AHR and
JAH. They weren’t really too negative. Archer thought that the book was “a marvelous
accomplishment and a testament to Bailyn’s standing as one of our finest
historians.” Pulsipher declared that it was the “kind of book that the word “magisterial”
was made for.”
I’m not sure to what extent Bailyn is regarded as an
economic historian, but his early work appeared in the Journal of Economic History and Explorations
in Entrepreneurial History as well as The
New England Merchants in the Seventeenth Century .
Here is some more recent work on New
England merchants and credit by David Flynn and Jeremy Schwartz
Monday, February 16, 2015
Economic Growth
This last week I have been reading Sven
Beckert’s Empire of Cotton and Sheilagh Ogilvie and A.W. Carus Institutions
and Economic Growth in Historical Perspective. Both deal with the
relationship between institutions and economic growth.
Beckert’s book reminds me of the
old saying that “There is much here that is new and much that is interesting.
Unfortunately, that which is new is not interesting, and that which is
interesting is not new.” The interesting parts are the discussions of the
industrial revolution (mostly Robert Allen’s theory), the role of force in
promoting trade (Findlay and O’Rourke, and others, have made this
argument); the capitalist nature of slavery (Conrad and Meyer and Fogel and
Engerman said this a long time ago). What’s new is the argument that cotton,
slavery and empire were not just important parts of economic history, they are
the key to how
the west got rich and capitalism was born. The book falls into the popular “________
that changed the World” category, where you insert whatever it is you are
writing about into the blank. It places too much emphasis on one part of the
economy: cotton. This is particularly true for the United States. We see many
references to the importance of cotton as an export, but we never see any
information about how important exports were to U.S. growth. The problem is that
economic historians for more than half a century have been moving away from
simple monocausal arguments about economic growth. Beckert declares that slavery
was the first big business, not railroads. But the new history of
capitalism is on no firmer ground making slavery the driving force behind
economic growth than Rostow’s non-communist manifesto was in making railroads
the driving force. The only difference is that much of the evidence about
railroads the importance of railroads was developed after Rostow wrote.
Of course, one can make the argument
that “Plunder may not have directly fueled the Industrial Revolution, but
mercantilism and imperialism were an important part of the context within which
it originated, expanding markets and ensuring the supply of raw materials.” (Findlay
and O’Rourke, xx) But Findlay and O’Rourke already made this argument in Power
and Plenty.
Sheilagh Ogilvie and A.W. Carus Institutions
and Economic Growth in Historical Perspective is at the opposite extreme.
For them the devil is in the details. One of their key points is that it is not
really productive to consider the influence of one institution in isolation;
particular institutions can only be understood within the broader institutional
framework that they are a part of. Beckert should have given more consideration
to this point because the most obvious problem with his argument is that the
institutions at the center of his story (slavery, expropriation, and the use of
force to control trade) have existed for a long time. They did not lead to modern
economic growth. If Ogilvie and Carus are right understanding modern economic
growth might be hard work.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)