This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Sunday, October 18, 2015
Christine Exley the Economic Rockstar
The latest edition of Economic Rockstar Podcast features Christine Exley of the Harvard Business School. Among other things, she talks about how she came to study economics at the University of Mary Washington.
Thursday, September 24, 2015
Disruption Disrupted
The Chronicle
of Higher Education examines challenges to Clay Christensen’s theory of
disruption. His The Innovator’s Dilemma has become one of the bestselling and most
influential books on business strategy. The
historian Jill Lepore wrote an
interesting critique of Christensen’s work for the
New Yorker last year. Now, Andrew King and Baljir Baatartogtokh have a new paper in
MIT Sloan Management Review, asking “How
Useful is the Theory of Disruptive Innovation?” King
and Brent Goldlfarb also have evidence of broader problems in empirical
research in management (the problem they examine is not unique to management
research). The Chronicle article is interesting both on the specific issue of
Christensen’s theory but also on the difficulty King faced in publishing a challenge to Christensen’s work:
“King and Tucci presented their findings at a
conference in 1999. King recalls sitting at a restaurant soon after and a
well-known figure in the field approached, shook his hand, and said,
"You’re the guy who burst Christensen’s bubble." But it didn’t turn out
that way. "We wrote a couple of papers, which we had to tone down a little
bit because of the referees," says Tucci. The paper — working title:
"Wrong. Wrong. Wrong." — was too polemical, they were told. When it
finally appeared in Management Science, in 2002, the article had been smothered
in theory and jargon. The published title: "Incumbent Entry Into New
Market Niches: The Role of Experience and Managerial Choice in the Creation of
Dynamic Capabilities." As Brent Goldfarb, an associate professor of management
at the University of Maryland business school and friend of King, says,
"You have to look really hard to realize King and Tucci slaughtered
Christensen." - See more at: http://chronicle.com.ezproxy.umw.edu/article/The-Undoing-of-Disruption/233101/#sthash.LUXodkFg.dpuf
The historian's craft and economics
My paper (with Mary Eschelbach Hansen) “The
historian’s craft and economics” is now available on First View at the Journal of Institutional Economics:
Abstract
History refers both to the past and to the systematic study of
the past. Attempts to make a case for history in economics generally emphasize
the first definition. There are benefits from increased attention to the past.
This paper argues that significant benefits can be gained from increased
attention to the systematic study of the past, the historian's craft. The
essence of the historian's craft is the critical evaluation of sources. Failure
to critically evaluate sources has the potential to lead to erroneous
conclusions, whether one is using historical documents or more recently created
data.
Saturday, August 29, 2015
Economics really needs better critics
Per
Byland recently complained that economists had killed economics
“What
we have seen over the course of the last eighty years is a systematic
dismantling of the contribution of economics to our understanding of the social
world. Whatever the cause, modern economics is now not much more than formal
modeling using mathematics dressed up in economics-sounding lingo."
I’m not sure that Bylund and Michael Lind would
agree on much, but Lind
also has seen the destruction of economics
“Before World War II, economics — the
field which had replaced the older “political economy” — was contested between
neoclassical economics, which sought to model the economy with the methods of
physics, and the much more sensible and empirically-oriented school of
institutional economics. Another name for institutional economics was the
Historical School. After 1945, the institutional economics associated in the
U.S. with John Kenneth Galbraith was purged from American economics faculties,
in favor of the “freshwater” (Chicago) and “saltwater” (MIT) versions of
mathematical economics, which focused on trying to model the economy using
equations as though it were a fluid or a gas.”
Either Bylund and
Lind are completely out of touch with what economists are doing now or I am.
Their critique of economics is an old one. I’m not sure it ever really applied,
but it does not now. The American Economic Review and other top journals are
full of empirical research, not lots of new papers about General Equilibrium.
What sort of work do
economists admire? Here are the John Bates Clark medalists since 1990. How many
are known as pure theorists and how many are known for the empirical research?
1991
|
|||
1993
|
|||
1995
|
|||
1997
|
|||
1999
|
|||
2001
|
|||
2003
|
|||
2005
|
|||
2007
|
|||
2009
|
|||
2010
|
|||
2011
|
|||
2012
|
|||
2013
|
|||
2014
|
|||
2015
|
Bylund and Lind seem to think that economists all aspire
to be Samuelson, Arrow or Debreu. Yes formal models with lots of imposing math
are still to be found, but more often than not they lead in to empirical
research.
Are there things that economist can do better? Yes.
I, for instance wish that economists would give as much attention to the
evidence that they use as they do to the formal model and the choice of econometric
techniques. On the topic, Mary and I have a paper on “The Historian’s Craft and
Economics” that I am happy to say was just accepted by Journal of
Institutional Economics. I also wish they would give more attention to
history generally, but I’m not really an unbiased source on that topic.
Round table on Edward Baptist's Half has Never Been Told
The September Journal of
Economic History has a round table of reviews of Edward Baptist’s book The Half Has Never Been told, with
reviews by Alan Olmstead, Jonathan Pritchett, Trevon Logan and Peter Rousseau. They
each address different aspects of the way that Baptist misrepresents the
historiography of American slavery and makes things up. Thanks to Alan Olmstead
for mentioning one of my
blog posts on the book. Many of the points noted in these reviews are similar to ones that I and Pseudoerasmus
made about the book shortly after it came out, around the same time it was
getting glowing reviews in places like the New York Times Book Reviews. I found
Logan’s review particularly interesting when it stepped away from what is
typically thought of as economic history. He concludes
I think as an economic historian I was so offended by the
books portrayal of economic historians I may have missed some of the bigger
problems.
Tuesday, August 18, 2015
Tariffs and the Civil War, or 95% of All Statistics Are Made Up
A recent letter
to the editor of our local paper argued that secession and the Civil War
were caused by high tariffs not slavery. The Confederate states were rebelling
against high taxes and big government. Apparently, they were really just Reagan
Republicans or maybe even libertarians (slaveholding libertarians). The author
of the letter made the claim that the South paid 75 percent of the tariff
revenue in 1859. I thought the claim was so outrageous he must have just made it up. It turns
out you can find this claim all over the internet. It turns out it even has
academic credentials behind it. Some people attribute it to Walter
Williams, but he appears to have gotten it from Thomas Di Lorenzo, who
attributed it to Frank Taussig’s The
Tariff History of the United States. Di Lorenzo, however, did not
provide a page citation. I suspect that he did not provide a page citation
because one does not exist. If someone can find this in Taussig please let me
know.
In any case, it is not true that
most revenue came from Southern ports. A small fraction of tariff revenue came
from Southern ports. In 1860 the Secretary of the Treasury reported the amount
of revenue collected in each collection district between 1854 and 1859. (Sen.
Ex. Doc. No. 33 36th Congress 1st Session). Looking at
1857, for instance, one finds that total revenue was $64,171,034. Most of the
revenue, $42,510,753, came as it did every year from a single port: New York.
The most important port in the South was New Orleans, which brought in a little
more than $3 million, less than half as much as Boston. Southern ports were not
even close to being the most important source of revenue.
There is no mystery as to why Southern
states seceded. They issued secession proclamations explaining their actions. South
Carolina was the first to secede, and the state’s proclamation does not mention
tariffs. It is entirely
about the perceived threat to slavery. It declares that
“A geographical line has been drawn across
the Union, and all the States north of that line have united in the election of
a man to the high office of President of the United States, whose opinions and
purposes are hostile to slavery. He is to be entrusted with the administration
of the common Government, because he has declared that that "Government
cannot endure permanently half slave, half free," and that the public mind
must rest in the belief that slavery is in the course of ultimate extinction.”
Apparently we are to believe that they were simply hiding their true
motivation, opposition to tariffs. I wish modern defenders of the Confederacy
were as honest as its original defenders.
Thursday, August 13, 2015
History, Facts and Life Expectancy
Earlier this week on twitter Peter Bent mentioned Richard Yeselson’s
review of Steve Fraser’s Age of Acquiescence:
the Life and Death of American Resistance to Organized Wealth and Power in Dissent.
One of the claims made by Fraser, and repeated by Yeselson, is that, although
life expectancy increased during the Gilded Age, “it is also the fact that the
life expectancy of white males born during or after the Civil War was ten years
less than it had been a century earlier” (Fraser, 2015: 39). He provides a
citation to Centers for Disease Control, National Center for Health Statistics.
That is the entire citation. It is not clear whether it refers to a publication,
a website, or personal correspondence. I checked the website for the Center. They do have statistics on life
expectancy, but I only saw ones that went back to 1900. Historical
Statistics of the United States has estimates of life expectancy, but they only
go back to 1850. They show that life expectancy at birth increased from about
38 in 1850 to 40 in 1860 and 50 by 1900. If these estimates are reasonable and
Fraser is correct, life expectancy at birth would have been between 50 and 60
years in the late 1700s.
There is one estimate that I know of life expectancy in the
1700 that is this large: Fogel, using family histories, estimated that life
expectancy was greater than 55 years in the mid-1700s.(Robert William Fogel, "Nutrition and the Decline in Mortality since 1700: Some Preliminary Findings," in Engerman and Gallman Long Term Factors in American Economic Growth.
Fogel’s graph appears to indicate that life expectancy did
not return to its mid 1700s level until the middle of the twentieth century. Personally,
I’m skeptical of the accuracy of these estimates. They are much higher than
other estimates. In the late 1700s, Wigglesworth estimated life expectancy in
the mid 30s in Massachusetts in the late 1700s. Recently, Becker
estimated life expectancy in the 1700s to be around 40, using data on people
who attended Yale. In addition, Fogel notes that members of the British peerage
had a life expectancy of only about 40 years in the late 1700s. It should also
be noted that Fogel’s estimates of large decreases in life expectancy are consistent
with estimates of large decreases average height, but there are good reasons to
question the validity of that conclusion as well. If there were no large
decreases in welfare reflected in average height, does it make sense that there
would have been large decreases in life expectancy. In short, much of the available evidence seems hard to reconcile with very high life expectancy in 1700s America.
I do find it
plausible that there may have been a number of factors in the early nineteenth
century that could have adversely affected health. Increased urbanization almost
certainly increased the spread of disease. In addition, there were new diseases
to spread, like cholera.
With some luck and a lot of work we will probably have more
confidence in our knowledge of health and welfare in the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries. In the meantime, I am inclined to believe Becker’s estimates for the
1700s. That would mean that life expectancy increased very slowly during the
nineteenth century, and then more rapidly after about 1900 as cities began to
invest in sewage removal and water purification. Chapter 3 of Higgs Transformation of the American Economy (still my favorite book on American
economic history and now free
from the Mises Institute) describes the impact of these improvements.
What is the point of all this rambling on about what we don’t
know? The point is precisely that, we don’t know. I know it’s a lot to ask, but
historians should take a critical approach to the evidence. Let people know
when something is still up in the air. There is really nothing resembling a
fact regarding mean life expectancy in the 1700s in America. There are a number
of widely varying estimates. Don’t tell people we have “facts” that we don’t
have. There are more, and more important, puzzles in history than what happened
to the Roanoke Colony. Perhaps I’m getting old and cranky, but it seems to me
that I have seen a lot of historians lately playing fast and loose with the
evidence in order to make their point. And many of their reviewers do the same:
they evaluate the book on how well it conforms to their preconceptions.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)