This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Thursday, June 15, 2017
Treasure Island
The New York Times reports on attempts to redevelop my old home. We moved to Treasure Island (T.I.) in 1973, when I was 10, and lived there until 1980. It was a Navy base, but most of it was occupied by housing for the families of enlisted men, mostly Navy, but also Coast Guard and Marines. Officers families lived on Yerba Buena Island. Yerba Buena Island (YBI), while Treasure built for the Golden Gate Exposition, a fair to celebrate the opening of the Golden Gate and Bay Bridges in 1939. TI was converted to a Navy base during the War. I don't remeber exactly when the base was decomissioned, but I think it was in the early '90s.
some interesting talks and a couple of articles
I’m surprised I had not come across these videos before. They
are from a conference at Williams College on Historical Persistence in Comparative Development. This was the lineup for the
conference
How Deep are the Roots of Economic Development?;
Fertility and Modernity
Enrico Spolaore, professor of economics at Tufts University
and research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER).
Forced Coexistence and Economic Development: Evidence
from Native American Reservations
Christian Dippel, assistant professor of economics in the
Global Economics and Management Group at the UCLA Anderson School of Management
4:30 p.m. Climate and the Slave Trade
James Fenske, associate professor in the Department of
Economics and deputy director of the Centre for the Study of African Economies
at the University of Oxford
8 p.m. Keynote Address: The Global Spatial Distribution
of Population and Economic Activity: Effects of Nature, History, and
Agglomeration
David Weil, James and Merryl Tisch Professor of Economics at
Brown University and research associate of the NBER
Engineers, Entrepreneurs, and Development in the Americas
William Maloney, lead economist in the World Bank’s
Development Economic Research Group, former professor of economics at the
University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign
The Effect of the TseTse Fly on African Development
Marcella Alsan, assistant professor of medicine at the
Stanford University School of Medicine, core faculty member at Stanford’s
Center for Health Policy/Primary Care and Outcomes Research
Malthusian Dynamics and the Rise of the Poor Megacity
Dietrich Vollrath, associate professor of economics at the
University of Houston
“Unfinished
Business”: Historic Complementaries, Political Competition, and Ethnic Violence
in Gujarat
Saumitra Jha, associate professor of political economy at
the Stanford University Graduate School of Business
The European Origins of Comparative Development
Ross Levine, Willis H. Booth Chair in Banking and Finance at
the Haas School of Business at the University of California, Berkeley
Bowling for Fascism: Social Capital and the Rise of the
Nazi Party
Nico Voigtländer, assistant professor of economics in the
Global Economics and Management group at UCLA Anderson School of Management
The Long-Run Effects of the Scramble for Africa
Stelios Michalopoulous, assistant professor of economics at
Brown University, faculty research fellow at the NBER, external research
associate of the Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy at the
University of Warwick
Intergenerational Mobility and Institutional Change in
20th Century China
Noam Yuchtman, assistant professor in the Business and
Public Policy Group at the Haas School of Business at the University of
California, Berkeley and faculty research fellow at the NBER
The videos of the talks can be found here
on youtube.
Here is Slave
Consumption in the Old South: A Double Edged Sword by Kathleen Hilliard at the American Historian
Erik Hilt’s Economic
History, Historical Analysis, and the “New History of Capitalism” in the June Journal of Economic History can be
accessed for free until the end of June
Friday, June 9, 2017
Some Recent Economic History
Podcasts
At the Economics Detective Jari Eloranta talks about war
in economic history, Nuno Palma talks about money,
trade, and economic growth, and Mark Koyama on State Capacity.
At Econtalk Christy Ford
Chapin talks to Roberts about the economic history of health care in the United
States.
Publications
At aeaweb.org Tim
Hyde describes the research of Hornbeck and Keniston on "Creative
Destruction: Barriers to Urban Growth and the Great Boston Fire of 1872." June
2017 American Economic Review, 107(6): 1365-98
The most recent Journal
of Economic Literature contains a review by
Stanley Engerman of Edward Baptist’s The
Half Has Never Been Told and Clavin Schermerhorn’s the Business of Slavery
and the Rise of Capitalism. Pseudoerasmus noted on Twitter that Engerman is
largely repeating what some of us have been saying for more two years now. Unfortunately,
it appears that we need to keep repeating it. Too many historians continue to
not only turn a blind eye to the shoddy work in Baptist’s book but to actually
present it as an exemplar of historical research.
Blogs
At NEP-HIS Blog
Kenneth Pomeranz responds in two parts to the work of Deng and O’Brien on
measuring economic performance in Chinese history.
Andrew Batson blogs that "the divergence over the Great
divergence is narrowing"; he also provides a link to an April 2017 updated
version of Broadberry, Guan and Li “China,
Europe and the Great Divergence: A Study in Historical National Accounting,
980-1850
Thursday, June 8, 2017
Private provision of public goods
Maybe I am writing this too early in the morning to see what
I am missing here. I really mean that . I feel like I must be missing something. Alex Tabarok argues at Cato
Unbound that he has a private solution to the problem of public goods. The
setup for his example is that there is a bridge that will cost $800 to build and
will provide $100 benefit to each of ten people.
Now consider
a dominant assurance contract. An entrepreneur agrees to produce the public
good if and only if each of 10 people pay $80. If fewer than 10 people donate,
the contract is said to fail and the entrepreneur agrees to give a refund bonus
of $5 to each of the donors. Now imagine that potential donor A thinks that
potential donor B will not donate. In that case, it makes sense for A to
donate, because by doing so he will earn $5 at no cost. Thus any donor who
thinks that the contract will fail has an incentive to donate. Doing so earns
free money. As a result, it cannot be an equilibrium for more than one person
to fail to donate. We have only one more point to consider. What if donor A
thinks that every other donor will donate? In this case, A knows that if he
donates he won’t get the refund bonus, since the contract will succeed. But he
also knows that if he doesn’t donate he won’t get anything, but if does donate
he will pay $80 and get a public good which is worth $100 to him, for a net
gain of $20. Thus, A always has an incentive to donate. If others do not
donate, he earns free money. If others do donate, he gets the value of the
public good. Thus donating is a win-win, and the public good problem is solved.
The first part makes sense. If you do not think that others
will donate, then it is clear that you should donate and get the refund plus
the bonus. My problem is the second part in which he seeks to show that a person
always has an incentive to donate by arguing that he also knows that if he doesn’t donate he won’t get anything, but if
does donate he will pay $80 and get a public good which is worth $100 to him,
for a net gain of $20. Thus, A always has an incentive to
donate. Economists generally define a public good as one that is non-rival and
non-excludable. Non-rival means that your consumption does not diminish the benefit
that I gain from the good. The non-excludable part means that once the public
good is provided it is very costly to exclude people for consuming it.
Fireworks displays provide a relatively obvious example. The problem with Tabarrok’s argument is that
if it is a public good A can use it even if he does not pay. If he believes enough
others will contribute, his choice is between contribute $80 and get $100 benefit
(net $20) or pay nothing and get $100 benefit (net $100). If he does not get to use the bridge because
he did not contribute that mean the good is excludable. Thus at least in this example
the public good problem appears to be solved by assuming it away.
Thursday, June 1, 2017
McCurry on Slavery's Capitalism
Stephanie McCurry reviews Slavery’s Capitalism in the Times
Literary Supplement. She raises interesting questions about the
implications of the treatment of capitalism and slavery in the New History of
Capitalism. I, however, find myself in pretty much complete disagreement with
her about two of the essays.
She declares that
“Baptist's argument
about enslaved labour in cotton "labor camps" as bodily torture is
completely persuasive. Walter Johnson made a very similar case, also
powerfully, in River of Dark Dreams (2012). There is nothing to argue with
here. Neo-classical economic historians beg to differ and have taken Baptist to
task, insisting that efficiencies were the result of the introduction of
superior strains of cotton seed. That technical fight goes on, but it is
largely beside the point.”
I can’t figure out what she could possibly mean by “beside
the point.” Isn’t the point to create interpretations of the past based upon
the available evidence? That is what “the Neo-classical economists” have done
and Baptist has not. It has long been known that productivity in cotton
production was increasing. Why? Olmstead and Rhode collected a large amount of
evidence to try to answer the question. They concluded that slaveholders used
violence to coerce maximum effort from slaves and then used innovation in seeds
to increase the amount of cotton that could be produced from that maximum
effort. McCurry seems to simply buy Baptist’s lie that Olmstead and Rhode, as
well as other economists deny the role of violence in the system. I am not
going to repeat all the elements of the argument here, but you can read my
earlier blog post to see why I believe Baptist’s argument is about as far
away from persuasive as an essay can get. The bottom line is that Baptistic
history should never in anyway be encouraged. History needs a big sign that
says “Do Not Feed the Baptist.”
McCurry also writes that
“Slaves were not
compelled by the power of the dollar - that is to say of capital - but by the
whip.”
The problem with this statement is that the first part is
contradicted by a considerable amount of evidence. There is, of course, plenty
of evidence that the second part it true: slaves were motivated by the whip. But
there is also a lot of evidence rewards were used as well. I am sure that my
saying this will be taken out of context by some people and used to show that
economists don’t believe that slaves were tortured, but nothing could be
further from the truth. Whipping and other forms of physical assault were
obviously widely used. There is, however, plenty of evidence that rewards,
including money, were used as well. See, for instance, Kathleen Hilliard’s Master,
Slaves and Exchange. If I remember correctly A Slave No More
also has an interesting description of an arrangement in which John Washington
was hired out to a tobacco factory. His owner got a fixed payment, and
Washington got a piece rate for everything that he produced above a specified amount.
The point I am trying to make here is that, while we should never downplay the
brutality of slavery, it is also a disservice to the history of African
American people to deny the diversity of their experiences. Slave states
occupied a very large territory with diverse environments. If you include the
rest of the Americas the diversity is even greater. Slaves produced a wide
array of crops, manufactured a variety of goods, and performed many different
services. The one thing they all had in common is that they were not free. Even
if they were well treated, continuing in that condition depended on the
continuing goodwill of their master (not to mention his continuing good health
and economic success).
McCurry finds Baptist persuasive, but when John Majewski
asks
“why Republicans
opposed the expansion of slavery if the South was as capitalist, modern,
diversified, thriving and innovative as the North”
she finds that
The answer he offers
is not only unpersuasive; it provides a good basis for the contrary view. The
North, Majewski concludes, differed from even the most modern part of the South
in one important respect: "the democratization of education and
innovation". "Slavery created a political economy antithetical to
long-term development", which explained why Northern Republicans fought
the expansion of slavery into the territories. Far from securing the kind of
material and ideological convergence that is crucial to slavery's capitalism,
Majewski's argument, like Shankman's, seems to confirm that slavery could
generate enormous profit for Northerners while retaining a distinct political
economy that served as a brake on national capitalist development.
Majewski provides considerable evidence that even in areas
along the border with very similar geography, slave states invested less in
education and produced less innovation. He shows that Republicans were aware of
these differences and regarded them negatively.
McCurry does not provide any evidence to contradict this
argument. She declares that
the critical issue in
1860 was not that Republicans saw slavery as a problem, but that slaveholding
Southerners saw free labour and industrial capitalism as an existential threat.
The slaveholders had once called the shots in US politics. But by 1860 the
slave South was not the leading edge of anything except pro-slavery
nationalism. It seceded and provoked a civil war over the future of the nation
and of slavery in it.
But wasn’t it both? If Republicans had not opposed the
spread of slavery into new territories, would Southerners have viewed them as a
threat to the existence of slavery?
Gavin Wright’s review for EH.net remains the most insightful review of Slavery’s
Capitalism
Tuesday, May 30, 2017
Quick Take on Bankers and Empire
I just finished reading Peter James Hudson’s Bankers
and Empire: How Wall Street Colonized the Caribbean
Here
is John Clegg interviewing Hudson for the Brooklyn Rail.
Here is a New
Dawn podcast of Hudson talking to Michael Dawson about the book.
Hudson describes the activities of America’s most important
financial firms in the Caribbean during the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries. I have been looking forward to reading the book because he studies
many of the same firms that I have studied in my work on trust companies. (Institutions,
Entrepreneurs and American Economic History: How the Farmers Loan and Trust
company Shaped the Laws of Business:
1822-1929; “A
Failure of Regulation?: Reinterpreting the Panic of 1907,” Business History Review October 2014; and
“Trust Company Failures and Institutional Change in New York, 1875-1925,” Enterprise
and Society forthcoming). He is also looking at roughly the same period
that I do, but he asks very different questions.
Hudson wants to understand how the actions of these firms in
the Caribbean were shaped by the combination of racism and the profit motive. He writes about racial capitalism, but do not confuse this book book with Baptist and Beckert style New History of Capitalism. They make grand
claims and portray their work as the result of intense archival research, but
their overblown claims are constructed from a secondary literature that is either
misrepresented or concealed, and the archival references are ornamental. Hudson,
in contrast, tells a story that is built from the ground up using primary
sources. It is a messy story, because that is the story that emerges from the wide
array of primary sources that he uses. I thought this quote from the interview
with Clegg provided a nice description of my impression of the book:
I think it has helped
me to understand that the project of “U.S. imperialism” was contingent, marked
by an incomplete hegemony, often notable for its confusion, experimentation,
and failure, defined through competing interests, and rarely triumphalist. This
is not to say that it didn’t exist—or that its effects in the Caribbean, and
elsewhere, were not palpable, bloody, or real. But there was always pushback
and, while the U.S. state often served as the intermediary for U.S. capital
in the Caribbean, oftentimes government officials tried to be a brake on the
activities of banks if they felt they were not in the strategic and economic
interests of the state. Before I began this project I don’t think I was aware
of the role of law and regulation in mediating the relation between banking and
imperialism. More often than not, banking expansion was an attempt to evade,
erode, or re-write the federal regulations governing banking activity.
The bankers in the book both compete and cooperate. They see
the potential for profit, but ignorance and prejudice often leave them stumbling
around trying to get hold of it. There are profits, but there are also
failures. They try to use both U.S. and foreign governments to their advantage,
but not always successfully. They see themselves as constrained by the law, while
also trying to change the law and take advantage of operating under multiple
legal regimes. The book reminded me of the end of E.P. Thompson’s Whigs and Hunters, where he describes
sitting in his office, surrounded by piles of papers, trying to figure out what
it all meant, because the story he had found did not fit into existing
narratives about the role of law.
I’ll admit that the economist in me sometimes wanted a
little more about the quantitative significance of the firms’ actions. In
addition, although the references to the secondary literature, including
business history, are extensive, Hudson does not address more social science
oriented history. There has been a lot of recent work on institutions and
financial development in history, including Latin America and the Caribbean (especially
work by Haber and his students), and I’ll have to give more thought to how
Hudson’s story relates to this work.
Those issues aside, however, the book tells an interesting
story, and I love Hudson’s commitment to building a stories from the primary
sources. Moreover, as someone who has written about the same characters, the
stories rang true to me. I have tried to tell very different stories about
these firms, but his descriptions of them and the people who ran them sounded
like the firms and the people that I found in the sources.
Friday, May 26, 2017
Loan Sharks
The Exchange,
the blog of the Business History Conference, posted a list of new books of
interest, and I noticed Loan Sharks: The
Birth of Predatory Lending by Charles Geisst, published by the Brookings
Institution. I hadn’t heard about the book before, but I was curious since
there has been a lot of interesting work on loan sharks in the last decade or
so. I was particularly interested to see if he cited my work with Mary Eschelbach
Hansen ("The
evolution of garnishment and wage assignment law in Illinois." Essays
in Economic & Business History 32 (2014): 19-46). I looked Geisst’s
book up on Google books and did a quick search. Our paper did not show up in
the search.
I assumed he must cite Anne Fleming ("The
borrower's tale: a history of poor debtors in Lochner Era New York City." Law
and History Review 30, no. 04 (2012): 1053-1098 or "City of
Debtors: Law, Loan Sharks, and the Shadow Economy of Urban Poverty,
1900–1970." Enterprise & Society 17, no. 4 (2016):
734-740.) But she did not show up in the
search either.
Michael Easterly ("Your Job is Your Credit: Creating a
Market for Loans to Salaried Employees in New York City, 1885-1920." The
Journal of Economic History 70, no. 2 (2010): 463-468).
Bruce Carruthers, Timothy Guinnane and Yoonseuk Lee ("Bringing
“honest capital” to poor borrowers: The passage of the US Uniform Small Loan
Law, 1907–1930." Journal of Interdisciplinary History 42,
no. 3 (2012): 393-418).
Louis Hyman (Debtor
Nation: The History of America in Red Ink).
Lendol Calder (Financing
the American Dream: A Cultural History of Consumer Credit).
I couldn’t find any mention of any of them.
I was beginning to think that the search function must not
be working, then I searched for Geisst and there were numerous hits.
Perhaps the search in Google books is flawed. I hope that is the case. Maybe it only
finds the name of the author. If the search is not flawed, I am puzzled how
someone can write a book that does not cite any of the recent research on the
topic. I assume from the low price that the book is aimed at something wider
than a purely academic audience, but I’m not asking for a detailed
historiography, just some references to relevant work.
Monday, May 8, 2017
Two Awards and Two Conferences
Between end of the semester grading and trying to work on the book on the history of bankruptcy that Mary Eschelbach Hansen and I are writing I haven't found much time to blog lately, but here are a few economic history things worth noting.
Two Awards
Dave Donaldson won the John Bates Clark Medal. Although the
prize
committee’s statement does not refer to him as an economic historian, it
emphasizes important work that he has done on historical topics. Most of his
papers are available here at
his website. Here
is a Q &A with the Wall Street Journal
Naomi
Lamoreaux was awarded the Lifetime Achievement Award from the Business History
Conference.
Two Conferences
The program
for the annual meeting of the Economic and Business History Society.
The program
the NBER Summer Institute 2017 Development of the American Economy. Be sure to
check back later because only two papers are linked right now,
Now back to the history of bankruptcy.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)