I think most people have a very vague notion of what the Industrial
Revolution was, and descriptions and pictures are not particularly helpful. You
really need to see a spinning wheel, a spinning jenny, and a water frame at
work to appreciate what was happening in the 1700s. I have been fortunate enough
to visit some great museums and see some of these things at work, but I don’t
have the opportunity to do that with my students. That is where Industrial Revelations
comes in handy. There are several seasons of Industrial Revelations, and I
haven’t had time to watch them all, but the first season with Mark Williams (aka
Arthur Weasley) is great for showing many important technological changes
during the Industrial Revolution. Here is a link to the textile episode,
which I think is one of the best.
This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, May 14, 2018
Thursday, May 3, 2018
Stop Telling Kanye to Read Ed Baptist
Since Kanye West decided that the World had spent enough time
paying attention to people that are not him, I have seen a number of suggestions
for Kanye’s education. More than a few have been along these lines
If he were to read Baptist, Kanye, like many of
Baptist’s other readers, could learn all sorts of things that are not
true. He could learn that
1.
Before Ed Baptist, economists and historians did
not believe that slave owners were profit seeking capitalists. Many
historians and almost all economic historians viewed slavery as a profit
seeking enterprise.
2.
Slave produced cotton accounted for more than
60% of GDP. Baptist
made up numbers and summed them in an approach to national income accounting
that defies all logic.
3.
The pushing system was a term that enslaved
people used. Ed
Baptist made up the term (see section 4.1; on second thought, just read the
whole thing).
4.
Economic historians don’t think slave owners
used violence to coerce enslaved people. This
is simply not true.
5.
Baptist shows that innovations in violence led
to innovations in picking that drove increases in productivity during the
antebellum period. He never provides any
evidence to support one of the central claims of his book. See
the link for the previous point and this by
Pseudoerasmus, and this by Olmstead
and Rhode. I should also mention Trevor
Burnard as one of the first historians to call out Baptist.
If we want Kanye to understand the brutality of slavery, how
about Charles Ball,
or Solomon Northup,
or Harriet Jacobs?
If you think he needs to read some professor, how about Daina
Ramey Berry? Maybe if Kanye gets through these readings we can come up with
some more, but let’s not contribute to the miseducation of Kanye West by
telling him to read Ed Baptist’s terrible book.
P.S. Stop telling anyone to read Ed Baptist!
Wednesday, May 2, 2018
Thoughts on Kochs and GMU
1.
Cabrera sounds like Captain Renault. He should
have actually said that he was “shocked – shocked to find that there were deals
like this”
2.
The deals seem pretty stupid in terms of the
level of involvement that the Koch’s wanted. I say stupid because they should
have known that it would look bad when it came out, and it wasn’t necessary. As
long as the president and provost want the money to keep coming in they will
make sure the donor is happy.
3.
Provosts and presidents can do that because universities
are like schoolyards.
5.
I will continue to judge academics at George
Mason, whether they are in economics, Mercatus, the law school, or any other
department or center, based upon what they do as individuals. That means that Mark
Koyama and Noel Johnson are among the best economic historians
working now, Robin
Hanson and Arnold
Kling are willing to play fast and loose with evidence to support their
claims, and I still don’t understand why Tyler Cowen gets so much attention.
6.
This is the third time I have posted something
critical of Democracy in Chains and I still haven’t gotten any Koch money.
Monday, April 16, 2018
Diane Lindstrom (1944-2018)
At the risk of making this seem like a blog of economic
history obituaries, I think it is necessary to note the passing of Diane
Lindstrom. Here is the obituary
from the University of Wisconsin.
Along with Robert Gallman, Lawrence Herbst, Paul Uselding
and others Lindstrom challenged the version of American antebellum growth
presented in Doug North’s Economic Growth
of the United States, 1790-1860. In Economic
Growth Doug argued that growth was driven by a combination of cotton exports
and interregional trade, in which Southern specialization in cotton generated
demand for the products of farmers and manufacturers, driving growth in the
rest of the country. Although some new historians of capitalism continue to
cite the theory to demonstrate the central role of slavery in American economic
development, Lindstrom and others had built a strong case against it by the mid-1970s.
She generated evidence to argue that the South was largely
self-sufficient in grain:
Lindstrom, Diane. "Southern Dependence upon
Interregional Grain Supplies: A Review of the Trade Flows,
1840-1860." Agricultural History 44, no. 1 (1970):
101-113.
And she went on to build an alternative explanation of growth
based on the case of Philadelphia. She showed that the development in Philadelphia
was largely driven by the regional market, rather than an inter-regional one:
Lindstrom, Diane L. "Demand, Markets, and Eastern
Economic Development: Philadelphia, 1815-1840." Journal of
Economic History (1975): 271-273; Lindstrom, Diane. Economic
Development in the Philadelphia Region, 1810-1850. Columbia University
Press, 1978; and Lindstrom, Diane. "American economic growth before 1840:
New evidence and new directions." The Journal of Economic History 39,
no. 1 (1979): 289-301.
Subsequent economic historians have expanded on her work. John Majewski, for instance, builds on Lindstrom’s argument
by contrasting the case of Philadelphia with Virginia, showing how slavery led
to conditions that did not promote strong local demand or support long term
growth: A house dividing: Economic development in Pennsylvania and Virginia
before the Civil War. Cambridge University Press, 2000.
I did not know her personally, but anyone interested in understanding American economic development needs to know the argument she developed and the evidence that she collected to support it.
By the way, if anyone is surprised that I, a student of Doug’s,
am posting this you should know that the third edition of North’s Growth and Welfare in the American Past
(coauthored with Terry Anderson and Peter Hill) states that “The spread of the
cotton economy in the South and the development of the cotton export trade are
elements of a well known story. It now appears, however, that economic historians
have overemphasized the pattern of regional interdependence among the South,
the West, and the Northeast (page 72)” and cites Lindstrom in the bibliography
for that chapter. Doug once told me that the only good thing about getting old
was that he knew lots of things that did not work.
Tuesday, April 10, 2018
John Murray
Sad news. John was both an excellent economic historian and a really nice guy. Below is the text of the email about his death from EH.net. He will be missed by many people and in many ways.
John Murray, Joseph R. Hyde III Professor of Political Economy and Professor of Economics at Rhodes College, passed away on March 27, 2018 in Memphis, TN at the age of 58.
He was born on April 9, 1959 in Cincinnati, and became the first member of his family to attend college. He worked at a variety of jobs to pay his tuition, including phlebotomist, house painter, roofer, and ice cream vendor, graduating in 1981 from Oberlin College with a degree in economics. He later added an M.S. in mathematics from the University of Cincinnati, and the M.A. and Ph.D. in economics from The Ohio State University, where he wrote his dissertation under the tutelage of Rick Steckel.
John taught high school math before pursuing his graduate work in economics. After finishing at Ohio State, he accepted a position at the University of Toledo, where he remained for 18 years before accepting the Hyde Professorship at Rhodes College in 2011.
He had a lifelong penchant for learning, spending a summer studying the German language in Schwabish Hall in 1984, and summers as an NEH scholar in Munich in 1995 and at Duke in 2013. He also spent 2009-10 studying Catholic theology and philosophy at the Sacred Heart Major Seminary in Detroit.
Murray was the author of two books and co-editor of a third. The most recent, The Charleston Orphan House: Children’s Lives in the First Public Orphanage in America, published by the University of Chicago Press in 2013, was the recipient of the George C. Rogers, Jr. Prize, awarded by the South Carolina Historical Society for the best book on South Carolina history. His first book, Origins of American Health Insurance: A History of Industrial Sickness Funds (Yale University Press, 2007) was named one of ten “Noteworthy Books in Industrial Relations and Labor Economics” in 2008 by the Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University.
He published book chapters, monographs, encyclopedia and handbook contributions, and numerous articles in refereed journals including the Journal of Economic History, Explorations in Economic History, and Demography. His clear, crisp writing style and ability to explain complicated economic concepts made him a frequent choice to write for the popular press as well.
His research interests were varied. His most recent work centered on coal mine safety, post bellum African-American labor supply, and families in 19th century Charleston. He published extensively in the areas of the history of healthcare and health insurance, religion, and family related issues from education to orphanages, fertility, and marriage, not to mention his work in anthropometrics, labor markets, and literacy.
He was a scholar and a teacher, who believed deeply in the value of a liberal arts education, arguing that “a rigorous education, based on the traditional great books, teaches students great things—compassion for others in the human condition, the value of striving for greatness, the need for self-awareness, and humility in those efforts.” He won awards for his teaching at Ohio State and Toledo.
He was the director of the Program in Political Economy, a rigorous interdisciplinary major at Rhodes College. He taught a variety of economic history courses, including courses on demography and economic development, as well as mathematical economics, freshman calculus, introductory statistics, and econometrics. Then on the weekend he donated his time to his local parish, teaching Sunday School.
He was also generous with his time on a professional level, frequently reviewing books, and serving as the Book Review editor for the Journal of Economic History from 2014-16. He was a member of the editorial board of four journals: Explorations in Economic History (2008-15), the History of Education Quarterly(2016-19), Social Science History (1996-98 and 2006-14), and theJournal of Economic History since 2015. He served as the Associate Editor of Social Science History from 2001 to 2006.
He was a trustee for the Cliometric Society and served on its Program Committees, and was active in the Social Science History Association, holding numerous positions. He also served on numerous university committees at both Rhodes College and the University of Toledo.
More than a respected academic and award-winning author, John was a devoted husband and proud father. As impressive as his professional accomplishments were, his career always came second to his family. Conversations with John would eventually lead to family, and hearing him talk about them left no doubt about his true passion.
John is survived by his wife Lynn and their twin daughters.
Sunday, March 25, 2018
The Annunciation by Henry Ossawa Tanner
If you are in Philadelphia you should go see it at the Philadelphia Museum of Art. Reproductions do not do it justice.
Monday, March 5, 2018
Quick Take on The Mystery of the Kibbutz
While the power was out this weekend, and I was free from
electronic distractions, I had a chance to read Ran Abramitzky’s The Mystery of the Kibbutz: Egalitarian
Principles in a Capitalist World. The book is a sort of economic history equivalent of good micro-history, or
good business history. It tells a particular story in great detail but uses that
story to shed light on broader issues. Being an economist, Abramitzky collects
and analyses as much data on the kibbutzim (one of the things I learned is the
plural of kibbutz) as he can to examine problems of free riding, adverse
selection, and brain drain. But the book is built around a very personal story.
His grandparents helped to found and fought to protect Kibbutz Negba; his
mother grew up there, and he clearly has fond memories of visiting there while
he was growing up. His aunt, uncle and brother still live in kibbutzim. He uses
the story of the origins, successes, and recent struggles of this and other
kibbutzim to address broad questions of equity versus efficiency, and of
material versus non-material incentives. There is also an interesting chapter
on the history of communes in the United States.
The book is a pleasure to read. And, although kibbutzim are
unique, the economic issues that they have faced are not.
Tuesday, February 27, 2018
What Happened to The Standard of Living During the Gilded Age?
Richard White devotes a chapter of his new book on
Reconstruction and the Gilded Age, The
Republic for Which It Stands, to declining standards of living during the
Gilded Age.
White writes that
“By the most basic
standards—life span, infant death rate and bodily stature, which reflected childhood
health and nutrition—American life grew worse over the course of the nineteenth
century. Although economists have insisted that real wages were rising during
most of the Gilded Age, a people who celebrated their progress were, fact, going
backwards—growing shorter and dying earlier—until the 1890s.” (page 475)
“The average life
expectancy of a white man dropped from the 1790s until the last decade of the nineteenth
century. A slight uptick at midcentury proved fleeting, nor was it certain that
the smaller rise in 1890 would be permanent.” “What this added up to was that
an average white ten-year-old American boy in 1880, born at the beginning of
the Gilded Age and living through it, could expect to die at age forty-eight.
His height would be 5 feet, 5 inches. He would be shorter and have a briefer
life than his Revolutionary forebears.” “Infant mortality worsened in many
cities after 1880.” (page 479)
White also notes the difficulty of creating historical
statistics but suggests that
“When these
statistics all point in a similar direction, they are worth of some attention.”
In general, White bases his interpretation on excellent work
done by economic historians. I do, however, want to argue that there is less consensus
than he seems to suggest. In other words, the statistics do not all point in a similar
direction when it comes to the Gilded Age.
I also want to point out there is a miscalculation in the statement
about height. White relies on Costa (2015) for the evidence on height; he includes
a version of the graph from Costa (see below) in which one can see that the
series hits its lowest point in 1890 at 169.1 cm, which translates to 5 feet
six and a half inches. I am sure that I would make many more grievous errors in
a 940 page book, but I had already seen the number repeated once as if it were
fact.
Nevertheless, the overall picture that White presents of material
well being during the Gilded Age is consistent with picture in the graph. Clearly
the most noteworthy feature of the graph is the decrease in average height and
life expectancy during the nineteenth century. The average height and life
expectancy fell relative to colonial ancestors before beginning to rise again
in the late nineteenth century. The timing of the movements in the series seem
to be consistent with each other.
Source: Costa, Dora L. "Health and
the Economy in the United States from 1750 to the Present." Journal
of economic literature 53, no. 3 (2015): 503-70.
I want to argue that the evidence of declining living
standards in the Gilded Age is not as consistent as White suggests. Estimating life expectancy in
the United States during the nineteenth century is extremely difficult and different
approaches have produced different estimates. They all suggest that life
expectancy fell during the nineteenth century, but they do not all estimate
that life expectancy reached its lowest point in the late, as opposed to the
mid, nineteenth century. Estimating average
heights is also difficult, and recent work suggests that the series reproduced
by White may overestimate the extent of the decline and place the low point too
late in the nineteenth century.
The United States did not have a death
registry for the entire country until 1933. Some states and localities
registered deaths, but we are left with questions about how representative they
are. One innovative approach to the problem has been to use genealogical
records (see Fogel 1986). Beginning in 1850 the Census began to ask
about people that had died in the last year, which can then be used to
calculate life expectancy. On the numerous shortcomings of both types of data
see Hacker (2010).
Source: Hacker 2010
The above figure is from Hacker 2010 and presents four
different series of estimates of life expectancy at age 20. Only the Haines
series based on census data shows in the late nineteenth century. Both the Pope
and Kunze series bottom out in the 1860s.
Source: Hacker 2010
The mortality rates for several large cities also do not
seem consistent with worsening conditions during the Gilded Age. There is a
reduced incidence of large spikes in mortality, though there also isn’t a clear
trend toward declining mortality rates until late in the 19th
century (See Haines 2001).
The nineteenth century height estimates are based, for the
most part, upon a large sample of Union Army soldiers. I say for the most part
because late nineteenth century estimates are based upon an extrapolation from
Ohio National Guard data. The figure below from Costa and Steckel shows the
part of the series that is inferred from the Ohio National Guard data.
Source: Costa and Steckel, Long Term Trends in Health,
Welfare, and Economic Growth in the United States
Economic historians have long recognized that there are potential
problems with these estimates. The problem is not just that they might be
biased, but that the bias might change over time. On the other hand, if shorter
than average people became more likely to join the army or the national guard
then our estimates might suggest a decrease in average heights that did not
occur.
Although the potential for selection bias was known, later
research found similar patterns for the antebellum period in a variety of other
populations, for instance Ohio prison inmates (Maloney and Carson 2008) and Pennsylvania
prison inmates (Carson 2008).
Bodenhorn,
Guinane and Mroz (2017) recently argued that sample selection bias is a significant
problem in the height data. Ariell Zimran
has attempted to match soldiers with their census records and use the
information to adjust for selection bias. He concluded that, after adjusting for
selection bias, there was still a decrease in average height of about .64
inches between 1832 and 1860.
Matthias Zehetmayer took a different approach. He developed
a more comprehensive sample of soldiers. Because his observation extended into
the late nineteenth century he did not have to rely on an extrapolation for the
years after the Civil War. The graph below compares Zehetmayers estimates with
previous estimates. His estimates follow the original until you get to
the extrapolation from the Ohio national guard. Zehetmayer finds increases in the 1870s and 1880s rather than a steep decline.
Source:
Zehetmayer 2011
There are a lot of evidence pointing to a decline in height,
but there is no consensus that about when that decline began to reverse or even
if it might be explained by selection bias. Zehetmayer's recent estimates do,
however, seem to be consistent with the life expectancy estimates of Pope,
Kunze, and Hacker, reaching a low point in the 1860s or 1870s rather than 1890.
I think White was right to emphasize the difficulties involved
in creating historical statistics. Like other interpretations of history our
knowledge of material well-being in the past has to be derived from the bits
and pieces that were left behind, even if they are not ideally suited to the
task. Although estimates are very consistent regarding a declining standard of
living in the ante-bellum period, they are much less consistent about a decline
during the Gilded Age. The most recent estimates of both height and life
expectancy seem toward rising standards of living during the late nineteenth
century.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)