This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, December 29, 2014
Is Economics Already Open Access?
We just got the December 2014 issue of The American Economics Review. It took me about 10 minutes to find ungated versions of all the papers.
Friday, December 26, 2014
An appreciation of E.P. Thompson
This is The American Conservative's Christmas reading list. Benjamin Schwarz, the national editor of The American Conservative, chose E.P. Thompson's The Making of the English Working Class.
"Steeped in English literature—see the constant, apposite, and often starling allusions to Bunyan and Byron, Defoe and the Bible—Thompson wrote powerfully, concretely, plangently, with an exquisite sense of cadence and rhythm. That style deepens this elegiac book, elevating it to a masterpiece of literature as well as of scholarship. This is a work, Thompson unabashedly makes clear, about history’s losers, and in its embrace of the losers, as well as in other ways, The Making of the English Working Class is a profoundly anti-progressive book. Its protagonists’ values and their 50-year struggle to resist being turned into a proletariat may have seemed merely primitive and retrograde to strident Marxists (and may seem so to progressives of all stripes today), but Thompson’s historical imagination and sympathy allowed him to see the value, and the tragedy, of lost causes."
"Steeped in English literature—see the constant, apposite, and often starling allusions to Bunyan and Byron, Defoe and the Bible—Thompson wrote powerfully, concretely, plangently, with an exquisite sense of cadence and rhythm. That style deepens this elegiac book, elevating it to a masterpiece of literature as well as of scholarship. This is a work, Thompson unabashedly makes clear, about history’s losers, and in its embrace of the losers, as well as in other ways, The Making of the English Working Class is a profoundly anti-progressive book. Its protagonists’ values and their 50-year struggle to resist being turned into a proletariat may have seemed merely primitive and retrograde to strident Marxists (and may seem so to progressives of all stripes today), but Thompson’s historical imagination and sympathy allowed him to see the value, and the tragedy, of lost causes."
Does History Need a Manifesto?
Peter Mandler and Deborah Cohen review The History Manifesto by Jo Guldi and David Armitage. The review provides an interesting and optimistic assessment of the current state of the discipline of history.
Here is an earlier review by Pseudoerasmus, focusing on the books false claims about economic historians.
Here is an earlier review by Pseudoerasmus, focusing on the books false claims about economic historians.
Thursday, December 25, 2014
Tuesday, December 23, 2014
Cotton, Slavery and Economic Growth
Recently, several historians (Edward Baptist and Sven Beckert) have
attempted to make slavery and cotton the driving force behind American economic
growth in the nineteenth century. I believe that they present a misleading view
of economic growth and the relationship between slavery and economic growth.
1.
Slavery was predominately associated with one
product: cotton. Cotton was a very important crop. It is true, as Beckert points
out, that cotton accounted for over half of U.S. exports on the eve of the
Civil War. But exports were only about 9 % of GDP. Similarly, cotton accounted
for about 23 % of income in the South, but the South accounted for only 26% of
U.S. income. See D. A. Irwin, “The Optimal Tax on Antebellum U.S. cotton
Exports,” Journal of International Economics 60(2003):287) Ultimately, the
value of cotton production was equal to about 6% of GDP. The attempts to make
cotton the driving force of the American economy misses one of the most
important finding of economic historians: do not get too focused on a single
sector of an economy (see Fogel on the railroads and McCloskey on the textile
industry in England). There is no Rostovian engine of growth.
3.
Slavery appears to have had a negative effect on
long run trends in per capita GDP. The more a region depended on slave labor in
the past the lower its per capita income now.
You can go to measuringworth.com and graph the log of per capita GDP from 1800 to 1900. Does it appear to you that the rate of growh declined after 1865?
Wednesday, December 17, 2014
If all else fails just make it up
In the Washington
Post today Jim Tankersley reports on the negative influence of finance on
the economy. He reports that “In perhaps the
starkest illustration, economists from Harvard University and the University of
Chicago wrote in a recent paper that every dollar a worker earns in a
research field spills over to make the economy $5 better off. Every dollar a
similar worker earns in finance comes with a drain, making the economy 60 cents
worse off.” I clicked on the link to the paper (Lockwood BB,
Nathanson CG, Weyl GE. Taxation
and the Allocation of Talent). As best I can tell it says no such thing. It
seems to me that the authors are quite explicit that they do not have such
estimates of the spillover effects of different occupations. They use a variety
of guesses about what they might be to examine the implications of their model.
More new "history" of capitalism
Sven Beckert has an essay in the Chronicle Review, markting his new book.
Historians “observe,
quite rightly, that the world we live in cannot be understood without coming to
terms with the long history of capitalism—a process that has arguably unfolded
over more than half a millennium. They are further encouraged by the
all-too-frequent failings of
economists, who have tended to naturalize particular economic
arrangements by defining the "laws" of their development with
mathematical precision and preferring short-term over long-term perspectives.”
The need to offer some vague critique of economics in everything
they write is one of the most tiresome features of the new historians of
capitalism. I suggest that he take a look at some of the work by economists
that examines the influence of differences in institutions and endowments on
long term economic performance: North, Sokolof and Engerman, and Nunn would be
good places to start.
“What distinguishes
today’s historians of capitalism is that they insist on its contingent nature,
tracing how it has changed over time as it has revolutionized societies,
technologies, states, and many if not all facets of life.”
Who does this distinguish them from? Business historians have
frequently made such distinctions, writing about proprietary capitalism and
managerial capitalism, or just varieties of capitalism. Or, consider the work
on the evolution of monopoly capitalism by Marxist scholars. Most of the work by new institutional economic historians is about how capitalist economies have differed from place to place and eveolved over time.
“For too long, many
historians saw no problem in the opposition between capitalism and slavery.
They depicted the history of American capitalism without slavery, and slavery
as quintessentially noncapitalist. Instead of analyzing it as the modern
institution that it was, they described it as premodern.
Some scholars have always
disagree with such accounts. In the 1930s and 1940s, C.L.R. James and Eric
Williams argued for the centrality of slavery to capitalism, though their
findings were largely ignored. Nearly half a century later, two American
economists, Stanley L. Engerman and Robert William Fogel, observed in their
controversial book Time on the Cross (Little, Brown, 1974) the modernity and
profitability of slavery in the United States. Now a flurry of books and conferences are building
on those often unacknowledged foundations.”
Why don’t the people doing the new history of capitalism start acknowledging
these foundations?
Special Issue on Piketty's Capital
The British Journal of Sociology has a special issue on Piketty's Capital. All the articles are available free of charge.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)