Here is the program for the Development of the American Economy section of the NBER summer Institute. There are links to many of the papers.
Here is the program for a conference on the history of capitalism. Although I have been critical of much of what has been labeled the new history of capitalism, there are some interesting looking papers here. I don't plan to go to the conference, but I look forward to seeing Sharon Murphy's work on bank financing and slavery at some time in the future.
Here is Jeffrey Beall blogging about a new paper on open access publishing (particularly the fraudulent form of it) by my colleague Margaret Ray. He provides a link to the paper.
Based upon this tweet, it appears that someone at Cornell's History of Capitalism Camp was talking about Mary Eschelbach Hansen's work on bankruptcy. She is, by the way, my favorite economic historian.
This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Tuesday, July 19, 2016
Saturday, July 16, 2016
Stanley Fish on Historians Against Trump
The New York Times published a remarkably
dishonest essay by Stanley Fish. Fish attacks a group of historians for
publishing a statement opposing Donald Trump.
Fish begins by making clear that,
while he is specifically attacking these historians, his remarks really apply
to all professors. Ironically, the historians make clear in their letter that they
are not all professors. Even casual examination of the list of historians reveals
that many are not professors. But Fish won’t let details like that get in his
way. (quotes from Fish are in bold)
“PROFESSORS are
at it again, demonstrating in public how little they understand the
responsibilities and limits of their profession.”
Fish
claims that
“They
suggest that they are uniquely qualified to issue this warning because they
“have a professional obligation as historians to share an understanding of the
past upon which a better future may be built.”
This is
a really nice touch. Fish has taken a quote from the letter, but introduced it
with a lie. Nowhere in the letter is it explicitly or implicitly suggested that
historians are uniquely qualified. To the contrary, the letter refers to other
groups that have already issued similar letters.
This is
followed by some more cutting, pasting and inserting by Professor Fish. He is,
after all, Professor Fish, which is the reason is being published in the New
York Times.
Or in
other words: We’re historians and you’re not, and “historians understand the
impact these phenomena have upon society’s most vulnerable.” Therefore we can’t
keep silent, for “the lessons of history compel us to speak out against Trump.”
I’ll
just include this statement about extraordinary hubris for the enjoyment of
anyone that knows who Stanley Fish. I wouldn’t be surprised if Fish himself
didn’t get a good laugh out of it.
I would
say that the hubris of these statements was extraordinary were it not so
commonplace for professors (not all but many) to regularly equate the
possession of an advanced degree with virtue.
He then
returns to his assertion that the historian’s claim to be uniquely qualified.
The
claim is not simply that disciplinary expertise confers moral and political
superiority, but that historians, because of their training, are uniquely
objective observers: “As historians, we consider diverse viewpoints while
acknowledging our own limitations and subjectivity.”
In
fact, no such claim of uniqueness is made in the letter. They don’t say that
all historians oppose Trump and they don’t say that only historians are in a
position to evaluate Trump. They simply state that they are historians and that
their position as historians has led them to believe that they should oppose
Trump.
Historians
do have to consider diverse viewpoints and acknowledge their own limitations
and subjectivity. They don’t all do it well. I spend plenty of time criticizing
bad historical scholarship, but that criticism presumes that historians should
consider diverse viewpoints and acknowledge their limitations and subjectivity.
In the
interest of acknowledging my own subjectivity, I probably should acknowledge
that I hate Trump with the white hot passion of a thousand burning suns. But
the evidence that Fish is lying is clear. Simply read the letter.
The Rise and Fall of American Economic Growth
I finally got around to reading Robert Gordon’s Rise
and Fall of American Economic Growth. It is an excellent book. Much of the
book is essentially an expansion of Lebergott’s Pursuing
Happiness. It describes the many ways in which the material conditions of
life (what they consumed, how they worked, and their health) were transformed
from 1870 to 1970. Gordon argues that economic growth this period essentially
created modern economic life: comfortable homes with electricity and clean water, cars parked out front, and all of this purchased with less labor hours and less onerous labor.
Much of the attention the book has received has focused
on Gordon’s argument that current innovations in information and communication
are not transforming life the way the earlier changes did and that the rate of growth is unlikely to return to the rapid pace experienced
for most of the twentieth century. This argument actually occupies a relatively
small part of the book. I also found this part of the argument to be somewhat
more cautiously stated than I think it has been in the popular press and in
blurbs for the book. While Gordon argues that some of these innovations were uniquely transforming and points to specific factors that he believes are
likely to slow growth (e.g. demographic change, education, inequality), he also
has suggestions for policy changes which might mitigate some of these headwinds
(e.g. reducing excessive regulation, policies to reduce inequality). In other
words, he doesn’t appear to believe that the current course is inevitable. He
also acknowledges that any attempts to make predictions about future
innovations are somewhat speculative.
His analysis of the causes of the “Great Leap Forward” also
seems reasonable, though I think he gives too much credit to Alex Field for
pointing out the technological innovations that took place during the Great Depression
and not enough to Michael
Bernstein, who emphasized these changes long before Field.
I do tend to disagree with Gordon and others who underplay
the transformation brought about by information technology. You can say that it
is only entertainment and communication but my children ages 17, 23 and 27 are
never without their phones. They use social media, they watch movies and tv shows.
They listen to an incredible variety of music. When I was a teenager you pretty
much had to pick one kind of music: heavy metal, or punk, or disco. My kids
listen to everything. They listen to podcasts on soccer, cooking, politics,
etc. They can’t get lost. A map is no further than the phone. Maybe it is just
entertainment and information, but it is a world of information and
entertainment in their hand.
I agree with Gordon that attempts to make predictions about
future innovations are speculative, but I tend to be somewhat more optimistic
than he is. In part, my optimism stems from the dismal performance of dire
predictions about the future. Read Jevon’s on the Coal
Question, or Alvin Hansen on secular stagnation.
Part of my optimism is also related to what I think might be
the chief weakness of the book. It tells the story strictly from an American
standpoint. The problem with this is that the same things happened in many
other countries. The United States is not the only wealthy country. One of the
things that I believe I learned from John Nye (listen to John’s Econ Talk on the Great
Depression, Political Economy and the Evolution of the State) is that you
might want to occasionally look outside of particular area to see if the same
thing is happening in other places. If it is, you might want to ask what are
the broader forces at work. I think that if innovations can travel across
borders and innovation is not isolated to Americans there are some good reasons
to be optimistic. Increased economic freedom and access to education in Asia
have the potential to dramatically increase the pool of innovators. I don’t
think that economic freedom is firmly enough established to feel completely secure
about this, but I think the potential is great.
Sunday, July 3, 2016
Robin Hanson on Slavery
Robin Hanson and Bryan Caplan
were having an argument about something called “Em.” I have no idea what Em is
so I am not writing about that. But the argument had something to do with
slavery, and it prompted Hanson to do a quick review of the literature and write
up a summary on his blog overcoming bias. I’m afraid that Hanson’s quick
review of the literature was a bit too quick. Some of the statements are simply
wrong and others can reasonably be contested. I posted these responses on his blog, but it did not seem to keep the links. Consequently, I'm posting it here as well.
He states that
Historically, even when slaves were common,
they were usually a minority of the population. (Beware, the term “slave” is
used in different ways.) About 10% in the Roman Empire and US south.
This statement is simply
incorrect. Slaves accounted for substantially more than 10 percent of the
population of the South. Slaves were as much as 57 percent of the population
(South Caroline) and at least 25 percent (Tennessee). See, for instance, Jenny Wahl.
Or you can check at the Historical
Census Browser at UVA
He states that
(The sex story is overrated, as only 1-2% of
slave babies were fathered by white men.)
The first thing to note is
that, unlike population, the number of children born to slave mothers and white
fathers is difficult to estimate. Some estimates put it as low as 1-2 percent,
but Stephen Crawford found that in ex-slave interviews, by the WPA and Fisk University,
as many 10 percent of slaves reported that their father was white. The 10
percent figure was when the interviews were done by African –American interviewers.
In other words we don’t know. It may be possible use genetic studies to produce
a more accurate estimate, but I don’t know of such a study. There is also the
question of “How large is large?” Stating that “the sex story is overrated”
suggests that 1-2 percent is somehow not important. Given that the vast
majority of enslaved people in the South lived on plantations of 15 or more
people, even 1 or 2 percent could be consistent with a relatively large percentage
of slave owners fathering an enslaved child (or a smaller percentage fathering
numerous children). It is not obvious to me that 1 or 2 percent is small in
this case.
He states that
Sometimes people sold themselves into slavery
for a limited time, as with indentured servitude.
This is just kind of odd.
It may be that he is using a definition of slavery that makes this make sense,
but I don’t know of any historian who regards slavery and indentured servitude
as equivalent.
Finally, he states that
Slaves weren’t
converted into debt perhaps because of credit market failures, or more
plausible because the full control approach was especially productive on
plantations.
I’m not entirely clear
about what this means, but it does not sound consistent with current
understanding of slavery in the United States. Historians have devoted
considerable attention to the well developed credit markets that facilitated
slave purchases. See for instance, recent work by Bonnie
Martin, John
Clegg, Calvin
Schemerhorn, Kathryn
Boodry, and Gonzalez,
Marshall, and Naidu.
Friday, June 17, 2016
Some Random Economic History
The
Program of the next meeting of the Economic History Association.
The Economic History Society now has a blog: The Long Run
Pseudoerasmus attempts to describe the essence of Beckert’s
argument about economic development in Empire
of Cotton
Jane Humphries
examines the role of women in English economic history and gives a lesson in
the use of primary sources in economic history.
At Ben
Franklin’s World Liz Covart and Zara Anashanslin also discuss the use of
primary sources, particularly in reference to Anashanslin’s book Portrait
of a Woman in Silk: Hidden Histories of the British Atlantic World.
Saturday, June 11, 2016
Fugitive Slave Ads and the Runaway New History of Capitalism
The OAH recently tweeted about a new post at the
Process blog. The tweet asked if
runaway slave ads can change the way we study slavery.The post is authored by Mary
Niall Mitchell, Edward Baptist, and Joshua Rothman, and it describes their new
project to create a database of digitized fugitive slave ads:
“Most historians of chattel slavery looking for detailed
information about individual enslaved people have turned to a familiar
constellation of sources: nineteenth-century slave narratives, the Ex-Slave
Narratives gathered in the 1930s and 1940s by the Works Progress
Administration, plantation records, and legal documents. We hope that this is
about to change, by bringing new and existing digital techniques to a type of
narrative that ran daily on the pages of American newspapers from the
eighteenth century until the Civil War: the fugitive slave advertisement.”
“By 1865, we estimate more than 200,000 such notices appeared.”
It is possible that there are 200,000 such notices. It
seems plausible to me, though I would be more willing to accept it if I was not
familiar with Ed
Baptist’s technique for creating quantitative estimates. He makes them up.
Although they do mention the work of Loren Schweinger and
John Hope Franklin on runaway slaves the overall impression that the authors leave is
that little has been done to make use of these valuable pieces of evidence. After
all, “historians …. have turned to a familiar constellation of sources,” but
they “ hope that this is about to change” as a result of their work. It is this implication that
they are boldly going where no historians have gone before that is the problem.
There are already a number of extensive collections
of digitized fugitive slave ads that, unlike their project, are already available
to people. Moreover, historians have long regarded fugitive slave ads as an important
source. Some economic historians have created databases including tens of
thousands of ads to conduct their research. Bellow I provide a list of some
of the digitization projects and historical scholarship related to runaway slave ads.
Can runaway slave ads change the way we study slavery? Yes. I know this because they already have. Why don’t the authors just acknowledge the contributions of the numerous scholars that have already worked on fugitive slave ads? They could simply state that despite all these previous efforts none has yet created a truly comprehensive database that is accessible to everyone. That would be true, and if they were able to create such a database it would be a considerable achievement. But that is not the way of the new history of capitalism. Instead, the approach is to ignore or deny the work of earlier scholars in order to claim false novelty for their own work.
“The North
Carolina Runaway Slave Advertisements project provides online access to all
known runaway slave advertisements (more than 2300 items) published in North
Carolina newspapers from 1751 to 1840. These brief ads provide a glimpse into
the social, economic, and cultural world of the American slave system and the
specific experience within North Carolina. Working from microfilmed copies
of these rare publications, the project team scanned the ads to provide digital
images, create full-text transcripts and descriptive metadata, and develop a
searchable database. The NCRSA website includes digital scans of the
ads, contextual essays to address their historical research value, full text
transcripts, an annotated bibliography to aid researchers, and a searchable
database.”
“The Texas Runaway Slave Project
(TRSP) is a database of runaway slave advertisements, articles and notices from
newspapers published in Texas. The project has so far documented the names of
over 1400 runaway slaves from Texas.”
“The
“Louisiana Runaway Slave Advertisements, 1836-1865” collection is a
comprehensive digital collection of advertisements and notices harvested from
the newspapers digitized as part of the Digitizing Louisiana Newspapers
Project. In these advertisements people from Louisiana and the Lower Mississippi
Valley demonstrate their agency
and resistance against the institutions of slavery and indentured servitude.
The project team identified and cropped advertisements
directly from the digital newspaper images, and they created full-text transcriptions and
descriptive metadata.”
“The Documenting Runaway Slaves (DRS) research project is a collaborative effort
to document newspaper advertisements placed by masters seeking the capture and
return of runaway slaves. Dr. Max Grivno and Dr. Douglas
Chambers, lead
researchers and faculty members in the Southern Miss Department of History, are
focusing their pilot project on Mississippi, but plans are already in place to
expand the research to the larger Gulf South, the rest of the southern United
States, the Caribbean, and Brazil.
“The Geography of Slavery in Virginia is a digital
collection of advertisements for runaway and captured slaves and servants in
18th- and 19th-century Virginia newspapers. Building on the rich descriptions
of individual slaves and servants in the ads, the project offers a personal,
geographical and documentary context for the study of slavery in Virginia, from
colonial times to the Civil War.”
Hodges, Graham Russell, and Alan Edward Brown. "
Pretends to be Free": Runaway Slave Advertisements from Colonial and
Revolutionary New York and New Jersey. Taylor & Francis, 1994.
Smith, Billy Gordon, and Richard Wojtowicz. Blacks
who Stole Themselves: Advertisments for Runaways in the Pennsylvania Gazette,
1728-1790. University of Pennsylvania Press, 1989.
Prude, Jonathan. "To Look upon the" Lower
Sort": Runaway Ads and the Appearance of Unfree Laborers in America,
1750-1800." The Journal of American History 78.1 (1991):
124-159.
Dittmar, Jeremiah, and Suresh Naidu. Contested
Property: Fugitive Slaves in the Antebellum US South. Working paper, Columbia University (September 2012),
2012. Dittmar and Naidu collected more than 20,000 ads.
Komlos, John. "The Height of Runaway Slaves in Colonial
America, 1720-1770." Stature, Living Standards, and Economic
Development: Essays in Anthropometric History, ed. John Komlos (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1994) (1994): 93-116. Komlos collected
more than 10,000 ads.
Tuesday, June 7, 2016
Loan Sharks
(Chicago Tribune Nov. 7, 1897)
Discussion about restricting payday lending has been in
the news recently.
We first became interested in how states regulated attempts
to collect debts from wage earners because bankruptcy rates look like this (see
Hansen
and Hansen 2012) Where it is easy to collect a large portion of someone’s
wages people are more likely to file for bankruptcy.
As best I can tell, something like payday lending has
existed about as long as paydays have existed. And as long as there has been
payday lending, people have worried about the negative consequences of it and
tried to place restrictions on it. In the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries, many state legislatures restricted the ability to use garnishment or
wage assignment. A wage assignment was a written statement that allowed the
lender to collect from your employer if you did not pay. Some states prohibited
wage assignments, others required spousal approval, or placed limits on the
amount of wages that could be assigned. Some employers also attempted to
prevent them. Armour, for instance required employees to sign a statement saying
they would not assign their wages.
One problem states faced in regulating small lending was due
process challenges. In addition to the due process clause in U.S. constitution
many states also have due process clauses in their constitutions. The legal arguments
involved substantive due process, which tends to raise fundamental questions
about the appropriate role and operation of government. (See Hansen
and Hansen 2014 on the evolution of garnishment and wage assignment in
Illinois)
Due process clauses tend to say something like “no one may
be deprived of life, liberty, or property without due process of law.” The first
thing to note is that you can be deprived life, liberty and property. It just
has to be done the right way. What does due process mean? There are two
aspects: procedural due process and substantive due process. Procedural is what
most people tend to think of when they think of due process. Did the state
follow the rules? Did you, for instance, have access to an attorney? You will
not find substantive due process in the constitution. It is a name given to
what courts were doing. Consequently, people can disagree about exactly what it
is. The description that best fits cases that I have read is that the court
asks if the regulation is a reasonable means to obtain a legitimate public
purpose. So, in the case of wage assignment restrictions, there was no question
that the rights of the wage earner and the lender were being restricted. The
problem to court faced was determining whether the restriction was a reasonable
means to obtain legitimate public purpose. Some courts said that there was no
state interest in interfering with how a grown man used his wages. Others said
that there was a legitimate public purpose because loan sharks impoverished the
working poor who then became a burden on the public. Behind the question of whether
a regulation of “loan sharks” is a legitimate public purpose is an even more
fundamental question: Who decides what a legitimate public purpose is? Is it the legislature or the court? Courts
went back and forth on this until the 1930s. Since the
1930s, courts have made a distinction between what they regard as economic
rights and what they regard as civil rights. On economic rights they defer to
the legislature. Consequently, cases like Kelo that may
surprise the public should not surprise people familiar with American legal
history. I think
legislatures are generally less restricted in their ability to regulate small
lenders than they were in the early twentieth century. Moreover, the federal government been in the business of trying to eliminate loan sharks at least since the 1968 Consumer Credit Protection Act.
On the other hand, I don’t think the fundamental economics
has changed much. There are three basic problems: low income people often need
to borrow money, they have no security for a loan other than their future wages
(and sometimes a car), and it is expensive to lend to low income people. As I noted
before, the problem is not new. People often focus on the interest rates and
suggest that lenders are making extraordinary profits by exploiting the poor.
The alternative explanation is that the interest rates are high because the
cost of providing such loans is high. I tend to lean toward the second
explanation. The primary reason I lean toward the second explanation is that I
don’t see substantial barriers to entry in small lending. If a lender is making
extraordinary profits by lending at an implicit rate of say 30%, why doesn’t another
lender enter the market, charge 28%, attract all the customers, and make a real
killing? Why don’t banks enter the market? They have reputation for liking
profits. Moreover, why doesn’t someone start a non-profit payday lender? The
non-profit should be able to easily cover its costs and provide lower cost
loans to people. Actually, people have tried things like this and failed. They
found that it was more costly than they anticipated. There are several good
reasons why it is costly. First, the loans are small, which means the administrative
cost tend to be a large fraction of the loan. Second, unlike banks that lend
other people’s money, payday lenders lend their own money, and thus have a
lower rate of return on capital.
So, what should be done? I don’t know. What I do know is
that getting rid of payday lenders will not get rid of the need that low income
people often have to borrow, and the more that you restrict legal options, the
more room there will be for illegal options. What we shouldn't do is take away the option without providing an alternative and then pat ourselves on the back as if we solved the problem.
P.S. Usury laws have also restricted the ability to legally
make loans to low income wage earners. They existed throughout most of American
history (see Rockoff
2003 on the history of usury laws and Benmelech
and Moskowitz 2010 on the political economy of usury laws.
Tuesday, May 31, 2016
Economic and Business History Society
I first presented a paper at EBHS in 1996 in Savannah. My
first, publication was in Essays in
Economic and Business History. I go to the meeting whenever I can take the
train or drive in a reasonable amount of time (say 12 hours or so), and I have
published a couple more papers in Essays.
EBHS has changed a great deal over the last twenty years. It has become much
more international. Many of the members come from Europe, and there is an
increasing number from Asia. Every other year the meeting is held outside the
United States. This year it was in Montreal. Next year it will be in Oklahoma City,
and in 2018 it will be in Finland. The editors of Essays have made it an open access online journal, with an
impressive editorial board. What hasn’t changed is that the EBHS meeting always
demonstrates that historians and economists (and even some business types) can
coexist, not just peacefully, but happily and productively. As long as the
methodology seems appropriate for the question, people just want to hear what
you have to say. The sessions are well attended, and the questions and comments
are thoughtful. EBHS is particularly welcoming of people just starting their
academic careers.
This year
Fan Fei
won the Lynne Doti award for the best
paper by a graduate student for his work on interstate highways and the decline
of general stores. Fei is graduate student in the Economics Department at
Michigan. You can find his job market paper here.
Soudeh
Mirgashemi won the Fred Batemen prize for the best paper for her work
on dams and agricultural development in the West in the early twentieth
century. She did her Ph. D. at
Arizona and just finished her first year teaching at Hofstra. Soudeh
presented at the same session as Nikola Tynan and Leslie Tomory. Nikola’s paper
(coauthored with Brian Beach and Werner Troesken) showed a large drop in typhoid
deaths following municipalization of water works in English cities. Leslie presented
work on the history of the London water supply. I found it interesting that he
said he began the work after he finished a book on the gas industry. Since
Werner also started with the gas industry (the Chicago gas trust) it suggests
there are economies of scope involved in the study of networks of pipe.
Brad Sturgill and Dan Giedeman won the James Soltow Award
for the
best paper published in Essays
the previous year.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)