The Exchange
had a post the other day about a special issue of the Journal of
the Gilded Age and Progressive Era focusing on the history of capitalism. Several of the papers looked interesting. Unfortunately, I discovered that I only have access to JGAPE with a one year
delay. My wife teaches at American University, and their access also has a one
year delay. I then took the next step of searching for open access versions of
the papers: working papers or papers presented at seminars. I put the title and
author of each paper into Google Scholar. I did not find an open access version
of a single one of the papers. I then tried the same thing with the first seven
papers in the August issue of American
Economic Review. Granted, this is a small and unscientific sample.
Nevertheless, the result is consistent with the impression that I have had for
a while that economics is more open access than history. What I am not sure
about is why. I think economists believe that there is no cost to providing
open access to working papers, and, as best I can tell, there is not. Do
historians believe there is a cost? Is there? I know there are concerns about
open access to dissertations reducing the demand for a book derived from that
dissertation. Are these concerns well founded? And what about journal articles?
This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Monday, August 1, 2016
Friday, July 29, 2016
Women and Econ Blogs
Claudia
Sahm blogged about the lack of women among econ bloggers
I looked at intelligenteconomist.com’s
list of top economic blogs an only found four (out of one hundred)
Jodi Beggs at Economists Do It With Models
Lynne Kiesling (with Michael Giberson) at Knowledge Problem
Muriel Niederle at Experimental and
Behavioral Economics
Economic History from the Last ASSA
Historical Perspectives on Financial Crisis, Banks and
Regulation
Presiding: Gary Richardson
Crisis and Collapse in the Long Run: Some Microeconomic Evidence Raghuram Rajan and Rodney Ramcharan
What Ends Banking Panics? Gary Gorton and Ellis Tallman
Interbank Markets and Banking Crises: New Evidence on the Establishment and Impact of the Federal Reserve Mark Carlson and David Wheelock
Commercial Bank Leverage and Regulatory Regimes: Comparative Evidence from the Great Depression and Great Recession Christoffer Koch, Gary Richardson and Patrick Van Horn
View Webcast
Presiding: Gary Richardson
Crisis and Collapse in the Long Run: Some Microeconomic Evidence Raghuram Rajan and Rodney Ramcharan
What Ends Banking Panics? Gary Gorton and Ellis Tallman
Interbank Markets and Banking Crises: New Evidence on the Establishment and Impact of the Federal Reserve Mark Carlson and David Wheelock
Commercial Bank Leverage and Regulatory Regimes: Comparative Evidence from the Great Depression and Great Recession Christoffer Koch, Gary Richardson and Patrick Van Horn
View Webcast
Critiquing Robert J. Gordon's Rise and Fall of American
Growth (Panel Discussion)
Presiding: Robert Shiller
Gregory Clark
Nicholas Crafts
Benjamin Friedman
James T. Robinson
View Webcast
Presiding: Robert Shiller
Gregory Clark
Nicholas Crafts
Benjamin Friedman
James T. Robinson
View Webcast
Monday, July 25, 2016
Evononsense and Homo Paleas
I was just looking at Evonomics.com, an important new source
of misinformation about economics. Numerous essays there talk about how economic
analysis is based on the study of homo economicus, a creature that is only
concerned about its own selfish material interest.
More specifically:
“homo economicus… is
the character that inhabits the economics texts, and the computer models that
are the silent dictators of analysis and policy. Econ, as I will call him, is a
myopic integer of self-seeking, who goes through life with a relentless and
unfailing calculus of personal loss and gain. He has no social affinities, is
oblivious of social context, and has no capacity or inclination to think of
anyone besides him or her self.” (Jonathan
Rowe at Evonomics)
It is easy to see how foolish those economists are and what
a waste of time economics is. There is only one small problem. The imaginary
being is not homo economicus, it is homo paleas. Homo paleas is an imaginary
economist created by people who want to criticize economics without having to
go to the trouble of studying what economists actually do.
Economists generally do analyze models in which people are
assumed to maximize utility, but these people can get utility from anything they
like. No real economist says that you can’t get utility from someone else’s
pleasure, or, for that matter, someone else’s pain.
What have economists actually said?
Adam Smith wrote in his Theory of Moral Sentiments that
“How selfish soever a
man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature, which
interest him in the fortune of others, and render their happiness necessary to
him, though h derives nothing from it except the pleasure of seeing it.”
Well, Smith was special. It must have been after him that
economists starting studying homo economicus. What did Alfred Marshall say?
Alfred Marshall wrote in his Principles of Economics that
“Thus though it is
true that "money" or "general purchasing power" or
"command over material wealth," is the centre around which economic
science clusters; this is so, not because money or material wealth is regarded
as the main aim of human effort, nor even as affording the main subject-matter
for the study of the economist, but because in this world of ours it is the one
convenient means of measuring human motive on a large scale. If the older
economists had made this clear, they would have escaped many grievous
misrepresentations; and the splendid teachings of Carlyle and Ruskin as to the
right aims of human endeavour and the right uses of wealth, would not then have
been marred by bitter attacks on economics, based on the mistaken belief that
that science had no concern with any motive except the selfish desire for
wealth, or even that it inculcated a policy of sordid selfishness.” (Book I
Ch. II).
Okay, it wasn’t Marshall. Maybe economists now think that
people can’t care about others.
In 2011, Andersen, Ertac, Gneezy, Hoffman and List explained
that
“where economics
provides its most basic predictions revolves around how people should respond
to changes in incentives—pecuniary or nonpecuniary (Gneezy and Aldo Rustichini
2000)—not whether subjects have fairness, spite, or altruistic proclivities.”
(Stakes
Matter in Ultimatum Games)
Because they analyze the actions of the imaginary homo paleas
rather than actual economists, these critics of economics think they have shown
the weakness of economics when they point out that people vote, or give to
charity, or are willing to incur a cost to punish economic experiments are
concerned with fairness. The trouble is that there is actually nothing in
economics that suggests a person cannot care about other people.
Economics theory does not suggest that people should not
give to charity. It suggests that people will do it more if you lower the cost
by, for instance giving a charitable deduction.
Tuesday, July 19, 2016
Some New Stuff
Here is the program for the Development of the American Economy section of the NBER summer Institute. There are links to many of the papers.
Here is the program for a conference on the history of capitalism. Although I have been critical of much of what has been labeled the new history of capitalism, there are some interesting looking papers here. I don't plan to go to the conference, but I look forward to seeing Sharon Murphy's work on bank financing and slavery at some time in the future.
Here is Jeffrey Beall blogging about a new paper on open access publishing (particularly the fraudulent form of it) by my colleague Margaret Ray. He provides a link to the paper.
Based upon this tweet, it appears that someone at Cornell's History of Capitalism Camp was talking about Mary Eschelbach Hansen's work on bankruptcy. She is, by the way, my favorite economic historian.
Here is the program for a conference on the history of capitalism. Although I have been critical of much of what has been labeled the new history of capitalism, there are some interesting looking papers here. I don't plan to go to the conference, but I look forward to seeing Sharon Murphy's work on bank financing and slavery at some time in the future.
Here is Jeffrey Beall blogging about a new paper on open access publishing (particularly the fraudulent form of it) by my colleague Margaret Ray. He provides a link to the paper.
Based upon this tweet, it appears that someone at Cornell's History of Capitalism Camp was talking about Mary Eschelbach Hansen's work on bankruptcy. She is, by the way, my favorite economic historian.
Saturday, July 16, 2016
Stanley Fish on Historians Against Trump
The New York Times published a remarkably
dishonest essay by Stanley Fish. Fish attacks a group of historians for
publishing a statement opposing Donald Trump.
Fish begins by making clear that,
while he is specifically attacking these historians, his remarks really apply
to all professors. Ironically, the historians make clear in their letter that they
are not all professors. Even casual examination of the list of historians reveals
that many are not professors. But Fish won’t let details like that get in his
way. (quotes from Fish are in bold)
“PROFESSORS are
at it again, demonstrating in public how little they understand the
responsibilities and limits of their profession.”
Fish
claims that
“They
suggest that they are uniquely qualified to issue this warning because they
“have a professional obligation as historians to share an understanding of the
past upon which a better future may be built.”
This is
a really nice touch. Fish has taken a quote from the letter, but introduced it
with a lie. Nowhere in the letter is it explicitly or implicitly suggested that
historians are uniquely qualified. To the contrary, the letter refers to other
groups that have already issued similar letters.
This is
followed by some more cutting, pasting and inserting by Professor Fish. He is,
after all, Professor Fish, which is the reason is being published in the New
York Times.
Or in
other words: We’re historians and you’re not, and “historians understand the
impact these phenomena have upon society’s most vulnerable.” Therefore we can’t
keep silent, for “the lessons of history compel us to speak out against Trump.”
I’ll
just include this statement about extraordinary hubris for the enjoyment of
anyone that knows who Stanley Fish. I wouldn’t be surprised if Fish himself
didn’t get a good laugh out of it.
I would
say that the hubris of these statements was extraordinary were it not so
commonplace for professors (not all but many) to regularly equate the
possession of an advanced degree with virtue.
He then
returns to his assertion that the historian’s claim to be uniquely qualified.
The
claim is not simply that disciplinary expertise confers moral and political
superiority, but that historians, because of their training, are uniquely
objective observers: “As historians, we consider diverse viewpoints while
acknowledging our own limitations and subjectivity.”
In
fact, no such claim of uniqueness is made in the letter. They don’t say that
all historians oppose Trump and they don’t say that only historians are in a
position to evaluate Trump. They simply state that they are historians and that
their position as historians has led them to believe that they should oppose
Trump.
Historians
do have to consider diverse viewpoints and acknowledge their own limitations
and subjectivity. They don’t all do it well. I spend plenty of time criticizing
bad historical scholarship, but that criticism presumes that historians should
consider diverse viewpoints and acknowledge their limitations and subjectivity.
In the
interest of acknowledging my own subjectivity, I probably should acknowledge
that I hate Trump with the white hot passion of a thousand burning suns. But
the evidence that Fish is lying is clear. Simply read the letter.
The Rise and Fall of American Economic Growth
I finally got around to reading Robert Gordon’s Rise
and Fall of American Economic Growth. It is an excellent book. Much of the
book is essentially an expansion of Lebergott’s Pursuing
Happiness. It describes the many ways in which the material conditions of
life (what they consumed, how they worked, and their health) were transformed
from 1870 to 1970. Gordon argues that economic growth this period essentially
created modern economic life: comfortable homes with electricity and clean water, cars parked out front, and all of this purchased with less labor hours and less onerous labor.
Much of the attention the book has received has focused
on Gordon’s argument that current innovations in information and communication
are not transforming life the way the earlier changes did and that the rate of growth is unlikely to return to the rapid pace experienced
for most of the twentieth century. This argument actually occupies a relatively
small part of the book. I also found this part of the argument to be somewhat
more cautiously stated than I think it has been in the popular press and in
blurbs for the book. While Gordon argues that some of these innovations were uniquely transforming and points to specific factors that he believes are
likely to slow growth (e.g. demographic change, education, inequality), he also
has suggestions for policy changes which might mitigate some of these headwinds
(e.g. reducing excessive regulation, policies to reduce inequality). In other
words, he doesn’t appear to believe that the current course is inevitable. He
also acknowledges that any attempts to make predictions about future
innovations are somewhat speculative.
His analysis of the causes of the “Great Leap Forward” also
seems reasonable, though I think he gives too much credit to Alex Field for
pointing out the technological innovations that took place during the Great Depression
and not enough to Michael
Bernstein, who emphasized these changes long before Field.
I do tend to disagree with Gordon and others who underplay
the transformation brought about by information technology. You can say that it
is only entertainment and communication but my children ages 17, 23 and 27 are
never without their phones. They use social media, they watch movies and tv shows.
They listen to an incredible variety of music. When I was a teenager you pretty
much had to pick one kind of music: heavy metal, or punk, or disco. My kids
listen to everything. They listen to podcasts on soccer, cooking, politics,
etc. They can’t get lost. A map is no further than the phone. Maybe it is just
entertainment and information, but it is a world of information and
entertainment in their hand.
I agree with Gordon that attempts to make predictions about
future innovations are speculative, but I tend to be somewhat more optimistic
than he is. In part, my optimism stems from the dismal performance of dire
predictions about the future. Read Jevon’s on the Coal
Question, or Alvin Hansen on secular stagnation.
Part of my optimism is also related to what I think might be
the chief weakness of the book. It tells the story strictly from an American
standpoint. The problem with this is that the same things happened in many
other countries. The United States is not the only wealthy country. One of the
things that I believe I learned from John Nye (listen to John’s Econ Talk on the Great
Depression, Political Economy and the Evolution of the State) is that you
might want to occasionally look outside of particular area to see if the same
thing is happening in other places. If it is, you might want to ask what are
the broader forces at work. I think that if innovations can travel across
borders and innovation is not isolated to Americans there are some good reasons
to be optimistic. Increased economic freedom and access to education in Asia
have the potential to dramatically increase the pool of innovators. I don’t
think that economic freedom is firmly enough established to feel completely secure
about this, but I think the potential is great.
Sunday, July 3, 2016
Robin Hanson on Slavery
Robin Hanson and Bryan Caplan
were having an argument about something called “Em.” I have no idea what Em is
so I am not writing about that. But the argument had something to do with
slavery, and it prompted Hanson to do a quick review of the literature and write
up a summary on his blog overcoming bias. I’m afraid that Hanson’s quick
review of the literature was a bit too quick. Some of the statements are simply
wrong and others can reasonably be contested. I posted these responses on his blog, but it did not seem to keep the links. Consequently, I'm posting it here as well.
He states that
Historically, even when slaves were common,
they were usually a minority of the population. (Beware, the term “slave” is
used in different ways.) About 10% in the Roman Empire and US south.
This statement is simply
incorrect. Slaves accounted for substantially more than 10 percent of the
population of the South. Slaves were as much as 57 percent of the population
(South Caroline) and at least 25 percent (Tennessee). See, for instance, Jenny Wahl.
Or you can check at the Historical
Census Browser at UVA
He states that
(The sex story is overrated, as only 1-2% of
slave babies were fathered by white men.)
The first thing to note is
that, unlike population, the number of children born to slave mothers and white
fathers is difficult to estimate. Some estimates put it as low as 1-2 percent,
but Stephen Crawford found that in ex-slave interviews, by the WPA and Fisk University,
as many 10 percent of slaves reported that their father was white. The 10
percent figure was when the interviews were done by African –American interviewers.
In other words we don’t know. It may be possible use genetic studies to produce
a more accurate estimate, but I don’t know of such a study. There is also the
question of “How large is large?” Stating that “the sex story is overrated”
suggests that 1-2 percent is somehow not important. Given that the vast
majority of enslaved people in the South lived on plantations of 15 or more
people, even 1 or 2 percent could be consistent with a relatively large percentage
of slave owners fathering an enslaved child (or a smaller percentage fathering
numerous children). It is not obvious to me that 1 or 2 percent is small in
this case.
He states that
Sometimes people sold themselves into slavery
for a limited time, as with indentured servitude.
This is just kind of odd.
It may be that he is using a definition of slavery that makes this make sense,
but I don’t know of any historian who regards slavery and indentured servitude
as equivalent.
Finally, he states that
Slaves weren’t
converted into debt perhaps because of credit market failures, or more
plausible because the full control approach was especially productive on
plantations.
I’m not entirely clear
about what this means, but it does not sound consistent with current
understanding of slavery in the United States. Historians have devoted
considerable attention to the well developed credit markets that facilitated
slave purchases. See for instance, recent work by Bonnie
Martin, John
Clegg, Calvin
Schemerhorn, Kathryn
Boodry, and Gonzalez,
Marshall, and Naidu.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)