This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Wednesday, January 11, 2017
Economics of Mixed Martial Arts Training
This is from bjpenn.com.
Firas Zahabi is the head coach at Tristar Gym in Montreal. he has worked with Georges St. Pierre and number of other UFC champions.
Here he is explaining why Ronda Rousey's problems as a standup fighter might not be entirely the fault of her coach. I actually think her coach is a big part of the problem, but I liked Zahabi's analysis of the problem, especially the last two sentences.
“The reason why a Ben Askren or a Ronda Rousey’s striking usually — not always — doesn’t hit that high level, is because they’ve spent so much time wiring their brain and their body and their nervous system to fight in one particular way. It’s opportunity cost. Every time you do one thing, you’re costing yourself in another.”
Friday, December 30, 2016
Economic History in 2016
This is my subjective assessment of some of the major developments
in economic history in the last year. Most of the papers I cite are from 2016
(or at least the versions I cite are from 2016) A few are from earlier, but you
can just think of it as the long 2016. It seemed long. By the way, I intend to
do a another post that focuses more on developments in American economic history.
Measuring Long Run Economic Performance
One of the most significant developments in economic history
over the last several decades has been the work to improve our estimates of
long run economic performance. Responding to challenges presented by Pomeranz’s
Great Divergence and obvious
weaknesses in Madison’s estimates, a number of economic historians have worked
to develop better estimates of economic performance in Europe and Asia over the
very long run. Economic historians continue these efforts but also recognize
the limitations of what they have done and, possibly, what they can do.
Stephen Broadberry has done much of this work with a number
of different co-authors. For a recent
example see Roger Fouquet and Stephen
Broadberry. "Seven
centuries of European economic growth and decline." The
Journal of Economic Perspectives 29, no. 4 (2015): 227-244.
Deng
and O’Brien raise numerous questions about the usefulness of these
estimates for Asia.
New estimates of long term economic performance have
prompted new attempts to explain differences in long term economic
performance.
State Capacity and Economic Growth
Economic historians have long recognized that the countries
that led the way in modern growth, England and Holland, also led the way in the
development of state capacity (the ability to tax and borrow to spend on public
goods.) But recent work has attempted to establish this relationship more generally
and identify the specific mechanisms by which state capacity contributed to
economic growth. Recent work has focused on the combination of state capacity
and constraints on state action. The problem, of course, isn’t new: it is the
fundamental Hobbesian problem, but economic historians are trying to understand
how effective solutions evolved.
See the survey paper on state capacity by Noel Johnson and
Mark Koyama (available through Noel’s website). The published version of Johnson and Koyama is "States and economic growth: capacity and constraints" Explorations in Economic History.
And this recent Economic Journal paper by Mark
Dincecco and Gabriel Katz
Religion and Economic Growth
Related to the work on state capacity, economic historians
have shed new light on the relationship between religion and early modern
growth. The idea that there might be some connection between economic growth
and religion has a long history. This connection was, for instance, central to
the stories told by Max Weber and R.H. Tawney.
What is new is that economic historians have gathered evidence and
employed techniques that enable them to identify specific mechanisms through
which religious beliefs and institutions influenced economic performance.
See, for instance,
Eric Chaney on Religion and the
Rise and Fall of Islamic Science
Anderson on Inquisition
and Scholarship
Jared Rubin’s forthcoming
book
Anderson, Johnson, and Koyama Jewish
persecution and weather shocks
Johnson and Koyama Jewish
communities and city growth
This
working paper by Dittmar and Meisenzahl
on the religion, politics and public goods in Germany during the Reformation
English Wages and Industrialization
Recent research on wages in England have challenged Robert
Allen’s theory of the industrial revolution. Allen’s theory was attractive in
its simplicity: relative prices drove the Industrial Revolution in England.
People invested in machines because labor was expensive and coal was cheap.
Several recent studies have, however, challenged the evidence of high wages in
England.
And these great videos
of Humphries describing the project.
See also Judy Stephenson’s work
on the building trades and her
blog post about the papers presented at a workshop on English wages.
You can also look at these blog posts for descriptions of
the state of the debate Pseudoerasmus and Vincent
Geloso. By the way, based upon the volume of tweets, blog posts, papers,
and working papers I am beginning to believe that Vincent Geloso must actually
be the name of a consortium of economic historians.
Note: This post was edited on December 4, 2017 to add a link to he published version of the Johnson and Koyama paper on state capacity.
Note: This post was edited on December 4, 2017 to add a link to he published version of the Johnson and Koyama paper on state capacity.
Thursday, December 22, 2016
My Response to Seth Rockman's Tweetstorm
I prefer blogging to tweeting. Below is my response to Seth Rockman’s
tweetstorm. His tweets are in bold.
2. @BAllanHansen Your piece on counterfactuals makes good sense. I also like the one by
Dietrich Vollrath
Thank you. I try
to make good sense. I also like Vollrath’s post
4. But when the
counterfactual is “pretend slavery didn’t happen,” then it gets bumpy.
Which economic historian has put forward this
counterfactual? I don’t recall it from Fogel or Olmstead and Rhode. I believe
that Robin Blackburn considered a counterfactual in which there was an early
abolition of slavery, but he is an historian so I don’t think this is referring
to him.
6. It is different
from “pretend there were no railroads.” It isn’t merely “academic.”
The debate over railroads was not merely academic. I tried
to make that point in my post yesterday. To the extent that Rostow’s theory influenced
policy, the debate over whether dumping a lot of funds into some targeted
leading sector could drive economic growth mattered. Robert
Wright has argued that the current argument over slavery and economic development
matters in a similar way: to the extent that you argue that slavery is a
necessary, or even useful, means of promoting growth it can provide support for
regimes that allow modern slavery to continue.
10. And although
economists have known slavery was capitalistic since Fogel, it seems delusional
to claim this is mainstream US knowledge
It is one thing to say that it is insufficiently recognized
by the public. It is another thing entirely to suggest, as Baptist does, that
economists and historians generally accepted that it was not capitalist.
11. Nor clear to me
what work economists have done to make this “commonsensical” in American
culture and politics... or in Econ 101.
Scholars like Fogel, and Wright have written numerous books,
many of them accessible to a general audience. It is in every American Economic
History textbook. Maybe economic historians need to take some marketing
classes.
14. Especially when
the haggling involves (a) pretending slavery didn’t actually happen
Saying something over and over again does not actually make
it true.
15. or (b)
privileging white testimony in problematic historical sources over black voices
in other differently-problematic sources.
Again, who are you talking about? Olmstead and Rhode’s
latest paper makes extensive use of slave narratives as well as plantation
records. It is easy to find on google scholar. And I am pretty sure that Trevon
Logan was not privileging white testimony here.
16. I’d be encouraged
if I thought economic historians were also grappling with slavery’s archive by
reading Saidiya Hartman, Jennifer Morgan
Good suggestions. At least listen to Jennifer Morgan on Liz Covart’s
podcast Ben Franklin’s World. By the way, I would also recommend Kathleen
Hilliard.
19. I will gladly
read more econ.hist. when econ. historians are really grappling with race,
power, & knowledge production—past and present.
You might try the literature on the negative consequences of
slavery, beginning with Sokolof and Engerman, and more recently Nathan Nunn and
others. You might also look at some of the recent work by Trevon Logan, Lisa
Cook, and John Parman. You can find a lot of it at Logan’s
website. Let me know if you want more suggestions.
Overall, my response to Professor Rockman’s tweetstorm is
the same as my response to much of the work that Baptist et al have done: he
continues to think that presenting a false picture of what economic historians
have said is a legitimate form of argument. When I criticize Baptist or Beckert
or Rockman I try to quote them. Rockman puts quotation marks around “pretend
slavery didn’t happen,” but he does not tell me who actually said this.
Wednesday, December 21, 2016
Counterfactuals and the Study of History
This blogpost was prompted by Marc Parry’s Shackles
and Dollars article in the Chronicle of Higher Education. Specifically,
the idea attributed to Eric Foner that counterfactuals are a waste of time.
There was extensive discussion of the issue on Twitter by Pseudoerasmus, Kevin
O’Rourke, Leah Boustan, Vincent Geloso and others, which Brad
DeLong collected, and a blogpost by Dietrich Vollrath.
What follows is my attempt to provide some background on the
use of counterfactuals in historical analysis and my thoughts on the extent to
which there is a methodological divide between historians and economists
regarding counterfactuals.
For any reader of this blog who is not an economist,
historian, philosopher, or science fiction fan, I would describe a counterfactual
history as an interpretation of the past that intentionally departs from
generally accepted evidence. The Man in the High Castle, for
instance, is a counterfactual. The generally accepted evidence is that Germany
and Japan surrendered; they did not win the war.
Historians asking people to think about how things might
have been is not new. Consider this
example from G.D.H Cole’s Introduction to
Economic History, 1750-1950 (first published in 1952):
“After delays caused
by the difficulties of internal migration, the displaced villagers and their
children provided the chief supply of labor for the new factories, and without
this reservoir of dis-employed labor the revolution in industry would perforce
have been greatly slowed down.”.
Cole is asking you to imagine what would have happened if
there had not been an enclosure movement in England. Such statements about what
might have been did not really attract much attention until a group of
economic historians started to write about counterfactuals in the late 1950s and
early 1960s.
To the best of my knowledge, Meyer and Conrad (1957) were the first to introduce the explicit use of
counterfactuals in economic history, making the argument that statemtns about causality always involved a counterfactual. Counterfactuals do
not, however, seem to have attracted much attention until Robert Fogel used a
counterfactual to estimate the extent to which economic growth was caused by
railroads in the nineteenth century. He asked what would the economyhave looked like if there were no railroads in 1890. He concluded that railroads accounted for a
relatively small part of the growth in the nineteenth century.
Fogel’s analysis prompted numerous critical responses. Some
of the critical responses from economic historians focused on the details of
Fogel’s counterfactual rather than the use of counterfactuals (David 1969). Some
traditional historians completely dismissed the use of a counterfactuals. E.P. Thompson referred to it as Geschichtwissenschlopff.
E.H. Carr called it a parlor game. David Hacket Fisher included the use of
counterfactuals in his book on Historical
Fallacies, referring to it as the fallacy of the fictional question. Fritz
Redlich called them “figments.”
Albert Fishlow also used a counterfactual, in his analysis
of the impact of railroads, but neither attracted as much critical attention as
Fogel’s work. Why did people respond so
strongly to Fogel’s work? Part of the response was no doubt due to Fogel himself.
He was not just an advocate for new methods, he was evangelist: Throw down your
old methods, and follow me, and I will make you scientific historians. But Fogel’s
counterfactual also required a much greater leap of the imagination than
Fishlow’s. It is much easier to imagine a world without the less than 30,000
miles of track that existed in 1859 than it is to imagine a world in which more
than 160,000 miles of track have been removed. Fogel compounded that leap of
the imagination by asking you to imagine a world that had adapted to the lack
of railroads by expanding roads and canals. Both used counterfactuals, but
Fishlow only asked you to get rid of the railroads and look at the roads and
canals that were actually there. Fogel is asking you to not just make a big
leap of the imagination but a very explicit one. Fishlow’s was not as big or as
explicit. It is very easy to slip into the notion of thinking of it as a parlor
game, or now a computer game, like Robber Baron.
Fogel’s counterfactual required a large leap of the imagination,
but it was not a parlor game. It is important to remember that Fogel’s argument
was not just against historians like Kirkland, it was against the economist W.
W. Rostow and his stages of growth theory, in which the take-off into self-sustaining
growth is driven by a leading sector like railroads. Moreover, the dispute with
Rostow mattered. Rostow had the ear of powerful people in the early 1960s,
people capable of actually influencing development policy (see Easterly 200 ,
31-33). In order to challenge Rostow,
Fogel needed to be able to estimate not just whether railroads mattered, but how much they mattered. Obviously many things were important to explaining economic growth in the United States in the nineteenth century. Fogel needed to be able to say to what extent, taking all those other things into consideration, railroads mattered.
Despite the negative responses to Fogel’s work, Foner’s
continued aversion to counterfactuals seems like a bit of history itself. Some
historians, such as Richard Evans, continue to oppose their use, but counterfactuals
have become pretty mainstream. Gary Kornblith (2003) has used a counterfactual
to examine the causes of the Civil War. Peter Coclanis and Stanley Engerman (2013)
debate whether slavery would have survived in the absence of a Civil War. Niall
Ferguson has edited a book of counterfactuals. Joe Crowley has edited two
volumes of What If. Bunzl (2004)
provided a guide to the use of counterfactual for readers of the American Historical Review. Rebecca
Onion argues that more historians should consider the value of counterfactuals.
Foner’s student Sven Beckert writes the following on page 97 of Empire of Cotton.
Even Foner is willing to discuss
counterfactuals.
I do think there are differences in the way that economists
and historians typically use counterfactuals. First, economists tend to use them
like Fogel to answer the question “To what extent did x cause y?” Consequently,
economists tend to focus on very precise counterfactuals that are embodied in
economic models, which incorporate all the relevant explanatory factors. (See Tim
Leunig’s survey
of social savings studies for numerous examples.)
Second, historians are more likely to deal with questions
where the answer to “What caused y?” is a story about a series of events. Consequently counterfactual tend to be like Kornblith's, describing a series of events beginning with Henry Clay
winning the presidential election in 1844, events that he argues were not just possible
but plausible and can shed light on the causes
of the Civil War. Counterfactuals in this cases are less about the quantitative
significance than they are about the role of contingency in history. The
actions of one individual or the repercussions of one event can make a big
difference in these counterfactuals. Any one individual is pretty much
irrelevant in a Fogel style counterfactual.
In the end, although
there are differences, I do not think that counterfactuals present a
fundamental methodological divide between historians and economists. Not all
historians oppose the use of counterfactuals, and some economists (McAfee 1983)
seem to think they are silly.
Finally, the statement attributed to Foner was misleading in so far as it suggests that there is fundamental methodological divide between historians and economists over the use of counterfactuals.The statement was also inaccurate
because the economic historians that have challenged Baptist et al have not
done so on the basis of counterfactuals. It is instead, Baptist et al who have
created interpretations that are not based on actual evidence. One of the
primary features of Baptist’s book is that he overtly and covertly makes things
up.
Bunzl, Martin. "Counterfactual history: a user's
guide." The American historical review 109, no. 3 (2004):
845-858.
Coclanis, Peter A., and Stanley L. Engerman. "Would
Slavery Have Survived Without the Civil War?: Economic Factors in the American
South During the Antebellum and Postbellum Eras." Southern
Cultures 19, no. 2 (2013): 66-90.
Conrad, Alfred H., and John R. Meyer. "The economics of
slavery in the ante bellum South." The Journal of Political
Economy (1958): 95-130.
David, Paul. “Transport Innovation and Economic Growth: Professor
Fogel on and off the Rails” The Economic
History Review, New Series, Vol. 22, No. 3 (Dec., 1969), pp. 506-525.
Easterly, W. The
Elusive Quest for Growth (2001).
Fogel, Robert William. "A quantitative approach to the
study of railroads in American economic growth: a report of some preliminary
findings." Journal of Economic History (1962): 163-197.
Fogel, Robert W. "The new economic history." The
Economic History Review 19, no. 3 (1966): 642-656.
Fogel, Robert William.
"The specification problem in economic history." The Journal of Economic History 27, no. 03 (1967): 283-308.
Gary J. Kornblith. “Rethinking the Coming of the Civil War:
A Counterfactual Exercise.” The Journal
of American History, Vol. 90, No. 1 (Jun., 2003), pp. 76-105
McAfee, R. Preston. "American economic growth and the
voyage of Columbus." The American Economic Review 73, no.
4 (1983): 735-740.
Meyer, John R., and Alfred H. Conrad. "Economic theory,
statistical inference, and economic history." The Journal of
Economic History 17.04 (1957): 524-544.
Redlich, Fritz. "New" and Traditional Approaches
to Economic History and Their Interdependence.” The Journal of Economic History Vol. 25, No. 4 (Dec., 1965), pp.
480-495.
Tuesday, December 13, 2016
Post-factual history: Seth Rockman edition
Pseudoerasmus sent
me a tweet by Seth Rockman.
The message refers to this
article on The
Other Slavery in the Chronicle of Higher
Education and suggests that economic historians will argue that slavery
never existed among Native Americans.
The Chronicle article notes that
The Other Slavery: The Uncovered Story of Indian
Enslavement in America by Andrés Reséndez “offers a capacious but defensible definition, including peonage; rebels
sentenced to servitude; orphans and vagrants bound to service; victims of the mita (a
forced labor quota imposed on Indian villages); and ostensibly free wage
laborers whose employers never paid them.”
This definition of slavery, which includes a variety of institutions that were used to coerce labor from Native Americans got me to wondering which economic historians Rockman will be the first to try to argue this away. Perhaps he thinks it will be my friend Tim Yeager author of "Encomienda or Slavery? The Spanish Crown's Choice of Labor Organization in Sixteenth-Century Spanish America." The Journal of Economic History 55, no. 04 (1995): 842-859. Wait, that article must be an aberration, economic historians wouldn’t let something like that or Ricardo D. Salvatore’s "Modes of Labor Control in Cattle-Ranching Economies: California, Southern Brazil, and Argentina, 1820-1860." The Journal of Economic History 51, no. 2 (1991): 441-51 into the Journal of Economic History. Maybe Rockman suspects that the firt one to try to argue it away will be Melissa Dell author of "The persistent effects of Peru's mining mita," Econometrica 78, no. 6 (2010): 1863-1903. Yes, Dell seems like a good choice, publishing in Econometrica is about as economist as you can get. Actually, I am a little surprised that Rockman had not at least heard of that paper. It has received a lot of attention. I thought it might be known to even someone who was adamant about preserving his ignorance of the work of economic historians.
Rockman’s own flexibility in interpreting the past can also be
seen in his reactions to the recent Chronicle article about slavery and
capitalism.
Last week the article highlighted the deficiencies of the
economists
Today the Chronicle article was just one of three articles
that tried to make slavery tangential to American economic development.
Such abrupt about faces would make my head spin. Moreover,
nothing in any of the articles suggested that slavery was “tangential” to
American economic development. Questioning claims that slavery was “the driving
force” behind economic development or claims that it accounted for half of GDP
are not even close to saying that slavery was tangential.
These guys are starting to make me feel like like Michael
Palin in this Monty
Python skit.
Saturday, December 10, 2016
Capitalism and Slavery Debate is not about differences in methodology
Marc
Perry wrote about the ongoing argument over the relationship between slavery and the American economic development that is taking place between some economic historians
(economists) and some new historians of capitalism (historians) Some people, including
the author of this
essay at the Economist, view the argument as a controversy over differences
in methodology between economists and historians. Several of the quotes by
historians in Parry’s article seem consistent with this view.
Personally, I do not view it as an argument about methods between
historians and economists. The economists, including myself, who have
criticized the work of Baptist and Beckert have focused more on their poor use of historical methods than their poor use economic methods.
There is no universally accepted description of appropriate
research methods in history or economics. People within disciplines often argue
about the appropriate methodology for the discipline. Nevertheless, I think
that most historians would agree that good historical work presents an accurate
historiography, so the reader understands the current state of the conversation
on the topic, and builds an interpretation of the past based upon an honest and critical interpretation
of the sources. Economic historians have criticized Baptist and his supporters
for failing to follow these practices, for failing to do good history. I haven't criticized Baptist and
his supporters for not having a formal model or not doing
econometric analysis. I have criticized them for misrepresenting what
economists and historians have written and said about slavery. I have criticized them for creating interpretations of the past that are based upon made up
stories and numbers rather than actual sources.
Misleading historiography.
One of the chief claims of Baptist and his supporters is
that they have overturned a long held view of the slave economy of the South as
stagnant and pre- or even anti- capitalist. This is one of the central claims
of The Half. In Parry’s article, Edward
Ayers echoes Baptist’s claim to novelty.
“What’s exciting about that approach is the way it renders the slave South as a
dynamic, changing society, in contrast to Genovese’s static, anti-capitalist
vision, says Edward L. Ayers, a historian and former president of the
University of Richmond. "To have that overturned so quickly," he
says, "it looks more like the sciences than it does the humanities."”
But these claims to have overturned long held views about slavery in the
United States are based solely upon a misleading historiography.
It is simply a myth that Genovese’s view of the economics of
slavery was held by the majority of economists or historians until Baptist and
Beckert cam along. While I think it can safely be said that Genovese’s work on
culture, such as Roll,
Jordan, Roll remains relevant, his work on the economics of slavery,
expressed in the Political Economy of
Slavery has long been discounted by both economists and historians. Consider
the interpretation of the South presented in an undergraduate text book three
decades ago: George Brown Tindall’s America: A Narrative History
Volume, 2nd edition (1988). Tindall wrote on page 371
that “More often than not the successful
planter was a driving newcomer, bent on maximizing profits. While the
profitability of slavery has been a long standing subject of controversy, in
recent years, economic historians have reached the conclusion that the slaves
on average supplied about a 10 percent return on their cost.” He went on to
note that slaves were the most profitable investment available in the South,
and that incomes in the South were not only comparable to the wealthiest
countries in the World, but that in the newer cotton lands incomes were among
the highest in the United States. The view that he presented to undergraduates
almost 30 years ago was of a thriving and successful southern economy based on
slave labor. There is no indication that he thought this was a controversial
interpretation.
Tindall was not an outlier, the interpretation in his
textbook was the standard one among. In 1995, Robert Whaples surveyed a sample of
both economists and historians who worked on economic history. He asked them
whether they generally agreed, agreed with provisos, or generally disagreed
with a series of statements. For the statement “Slavery
was a system irrationally kept in existence by plantation owners who failed to
perceive or were indifferent to their best economic interests,” ninety-three
percent of economists and ninety percent of historians disagreed with the
statement. For the statement “The
slave system was economically moribund on the eve of the Civil War,” ninety-eight
percent of economists and ninety-five percent of historians disagreed.
It is not just the claims about the nature of slavery in the
American South that Baptist and his supporters misrepresent. I argued in another
blogpost
that Baptist’s entire argument against Rhode and Olmstead is about misrepresenting
their argument. Beckert also claims an inordinate amount of novelty for his
argument about the role of force (“war capitalism”) by choosing not to cite
works like Findlay and O’Rourke’s Power
and Plenty.
Creating interpretations of the past that are not based
on evidence.
The claims about the size of
the economic impact of slavery have not been based upon the available evidence. For instance, "The slave economy of the Southern states had ripple effects
throughout the economy," Beckert wrote, "not just shaping but
dominating it." Or according to Baptist “ All told more than $600
million, or almost half of the economic activity in the United States in 1836,
derived directly or indirectly from cotton produced by the million odd slaves―
6 percent of the total US population―who in that year toiled in labor camps on
slavery’s frontier.” Beckert makes the claim that slave
produced cotton was the driving force based upon its predominant role among
exports, and Baptist simply makes up the numbers that he uses to make his “estimate.”
In contrast, economic historians have noted that
1. Cotton was the largest export from the U.S., but exports
were only about 9 % of GDP. Similarly, cotton accounted for about 23 % of
income in the South, but the South accounted for only 26% of U.S. income. See
D. A. Irwin, “The Optimal Tax on Antebellum U.S. Cotton Exports,” Journal of International Economics
60(2003):287) Ultimately, the value of cotton production was equal to about 6%
of GDP.
2. The South had lower average incomes than the North; and
per capita income was growing more slowly in the South even before the Civil
War. See Unequal
Gains by Lindert and Williamson Chapter 5. In addition, about twice as
many people lived in the Union states.
3. The more important slavery was in a country or state the
lower the level of income was in the future. Nathan Nunn “Slavery,
Inequality and Economic Development in the Americas: An Examination of the
Engerman-Sokoloff Argument (October 2007).
4. Slave states had lower levels of educational attainement and less innovation (measured by patents) than states without slavery. This was true even in the areas that were most like the North in geogrpahy and economic activity. See John Majewski "Why Did Northerners Oppose the Expansion of Slavery? Economic Developemnt and Education in the Limestone South" Chapter 14 in Slavery's Capitalsm.
4. Slave states had lower levels of educational attainement and less innovation (measured by patents) than states without slavery. This was true even in the areas that were most like the North in geogrpahy and economic activity. See John Majewski "Why Did Northerners Oppose the Expansion of Slavery? Economic Developemnt and Education in the Limestone South" Chapter 14 in Slavery's Capitalsm.
Foner complains that for the economic historian history “is just a source of numbers, a source of
data to throw into their equations." History is not just a source of
numbers, but, if you are going to use numbers, shouldn’t they come from
history, not the historian’s imagination? The current dispute is not about economic methods
versus historical methods; it is about bad history. Because it is about bad history, it is all the more disappointing when historians like Foner, who know better, are willing to stand behind it. After his NYTimes review of Baptist's book I wrote a post titled "et tu Foner?"
Economic historians have criticized Baptist and his
supporters because they are doing bad history. By the way, throughout this post
I have used the phrase Baptist and his supporters not historians because I do
not believe that they represent the discipline of history. There is far too
much really good work being done to take the worst work as representative of
the discipline. More than a few historians have questioned his historiography,
his propensity to make things up, and his use of sources (see for instance this
Historically Thinking
podcast). After reading Slavery’s
Capitalism I am not even convinced that Baptist and his supporters
represent people who regard themselves as historians of capitalism.
Caitlin Rosenthal, for instance, said she would like to promote more cooperation between economists and historians (and I thought her paper in Slavery's Capitalism was consistent with this statment). Carlo Cipolla long ago noted that there are differences between economists and historians, but he argued these differences should complement not conflict with each other. Mary and I recently argued in the Journal of Institutional Economics that economists had much to gain by paying more attention to the historian’s craft. Finally, Kevin O’Rourke pointed out on twitter that the economic history department at Oxford has both economists and historians, and they seem to get along just fine.
Note: This post was edited on 11 December 2016 to add point number 4 in the list above and the reference to John Majewski's paper on the Limestone South.
Note: This post was edited on 11 December 2016 to add point number 4 in the list above and the reference to John Majewski's paper on the Limestone South.
Thursday, December 8, 2016
The New Post-Factual History
The Chronicle of Higher
Education has published “Shackles
and Dollars,” an article on the forum on slavery and capitalism that was
held at Dartmouth. Dough Irwin moderated a discussion between Caitlin Rosenthal,
Sven Beckert, Alan Olmstead and Trevon Logan. While reading the article, I
realized that I had not really appreciated how revolutionary the work of Edward
Baptist and his supporters is. I had
thought that it was just bad history: misleading historiography, misrepresenting
the work of others, omitting evidence that is inconsistent with your claim, not
providing evidence to support your claim, and simply making up evidence. Yes,
it is true that in the past these things were regarded as characteristics of
bad historical work, but that is the past. Baptist is on the cutting edge of
bringing standards of historical scholarship in to line with a post-factual age.
Baptist and his supporters are less interested in changing the questions that
historians focus on than they are in changing the methods that historians use
to answer questions. It is not the new history of capitalism; it is the new post-factual
history.
Eric
Foner is onboard. He tells us that the economic historians who point out that Baptist
is just making stuff up are “champion nitpickers.” Foner declares that “I’m sure there are good, legitimate
criticisms of the handling of economic data. But in some ways I think it’s
almost irrelevant to the fundamental thrust of these works." The thrust
of Baptist’s book (other than the style in which it is written) are the claim
that unlike previous economists and historians he shows that the slave South
was a capitalist system, the claim that slave grown cotton was the driving
force behind economic growth, and the claim that the increases in cotton
production were driven by ever more intense use of torture. The first claim is
demonstrably false: The vast majority of economic historians, as well as many
other historians, had long regraded slave owners as capitalists driven by
profit motives (see this 1995
survey of economic historians conducted by Robert Whaples). Baptist’s only
evidence to support the second claim is a
series of numbers that he makes up and then proceeds to sum ; he does
appear to be able to do at least some basic addition. (See Pseudoerasmus for an extensive critique of the cotton driven
growth argument, as well as pretty much everything else Baptist says; see also my blogpost.) For the last claim Baptist
provides no evidence in support of his argument and omits evidence that is
inconsistent with his argument. When people challenge his argument his response
is always the same: throw
up a straw man and beat it to pieces. But, of course, all this is merely
nitpicking. The critical evaluation of evidence is irrelevant to the fundamental
thrust of the work.
The
article also notes that “For all the mudslinging, the slavery fight does not
break cleanly along disciplinary lines. Historians under attack find support
for their ideas in the writing of some
economists, like Ronald Findlay and Kevin H. O’Rourke. What the article
does not note is that Beckert’s book never mentions that Findlay and O’Rourke
had made a similar argument six years earlier. As a matter of fact, Beckert
does not cite Power and Plenty at all
in his book. That is probably just more nitpicking.
The
degree to which Baptist and his supporters seek a post-factual history was
brought home to me again when I saw that Seth Rockman had
tweeted that “new CHE article highlights economists thinking ahistorically
and ahistoriographically.” Read the article and judge for yourself. I will,
however, point out that the article notes that “Historians and economists
criticize the new slavery scholarship on grounds that go beyond economics.” And
it gives the last word to the economist Trevon Logan: “Like many others, Baptist "continues to see the enslaved as a
vehicle for his own need to tell us something new, even when it is not,"
Logan writes. "That, I believe, is the true shame about the historiography
of slavery."”
If you are a historian or simply someone interested in history. Read Beckert and Baptist, but also read Rhode and Olmstead, and Logan. Read them all carefully and critically. If you are persuaded by, for instance, Ed Baptist's calculation of the quantitative impact of slavery (page 321-22 of The Half), please tell me what you found persuasive about it.
Friday, December 2, 2016
Pope Francis and Economics
The latest issue of the Independent Review
is devoted to consideration of the relationship between Pope Francis and
economics. The
Introduction is by Robert Whaples. He is a good economic
historian, and I hope that I am being fair to his argument. That said, I do take issue with at least part
of the argument. Specifically, he states that “It is clear that Pope Francis
and many in the economics profession do not see eye to eye at a fundamental
level.” He then proceeds to argue that Pope Francis’s views are inconsistent
with fundamental assumptions of economic theory. To make the point clear he
refers to the description of the assumptions about consumer behavior in Pindyck
and Rubinfled’s microeconomics text :“[C]onsumers always prefer more of any
good to less . . . [and] are never satisfied or satiated; more is always
better, even if just a little better. (Pindyck and Rubinfeld 2005, 66)" He
points out that this assumption is also known as “nonsatiation.”
Whaples then argues that the assumption of non-satiation
gives rise to a fundamental difference between economists and Pope Francis:
“As shown earlier, Pope Francis’s view of the world is that
one of these foundational assumptions is assuredly invalid. This simply isn’t
how God made people. Christianity holds that God made man in His own image. In
many cases, this relationship can make man capable of the rationality that goes
into the first two assumptions about consumer choice—that preferences are
complete and transitive—but the third assumption is fundamentally flawed, says
Francis. More material possessions and greater consumption aren’t always or
even generally better. A consumer who never feels satisfied with his material
life—who always wants more—is not on the path to God.”
Whaples argument, however, misconstrues both what economists
do and what Pope Francis is trying to do. First, notice the difference between
what Pindyck and Rubinfled say and what Whaples says. Pindyck and Rubinfeld
assume that “[C]onsumers always prefer more of any good to less . . . [and] are
never satisfied or satiated.” Whaples suggests that Francis believes that “More
material possessions and greater consumption aren’t always or even generally
better.” Whaples switched from “goods” to “material possessions” and “consumption.”
A “good” in economic is anything that a person derives satisfaction (utility)
from. A good does not have to be a material possession or something that is
generally described as consumption. Whaples is perpetuating one of the most
common misconceptions about economics: the belief that economists think people
are only interested in their own material well-being, narrowly conceived.
People who believe that economists think this way have suggested that voting
for interest is inconsistent with economic theory because your vote will not affect
the outcome of an election, and therefore will not affect your material well-being.
But voting is just as consistent with economic theory as buying a new car. Economic
theory does not say what you will or will not get utility from. You can get
utility from buying a car, or voting, or going out to dinner, or praying, or
buying a diamond ring, or giving to charity, or even from eating this.
The things that give people satisfaction are usually the result of culture,
personal history, and individual tendencies.
No matter what your preferences, however, you still face the
fundamental problem of choice in the face of scarcity. I tell my students it
doesn’t matter whether you are Donald Trump or Mother Teresa you have to make
choices about how to allocate the resources you have. By the way, I used the
Donald in the example long before the election. Even if you only seek to serve
God you have time make choices about how to allocate your limited resources,
especially time. Francis himself has to choose between time spent in prayer,
time hearing confession, time celebrating Mass, time spent on writing
encyclicals, time spent meeting with Bishops, and time spent on his many
administrative duties as the head of the church.
If economic theory does not say what people want, what does
it do? Economic theory says that if people derive satisfaction from something
they are likely to do it more if the cost of doing it decreases and likely to
do it less if the cost of doing it increases. What economists get out of their
models of consumer behavior is predictions about how people will respond to
changes in the constraints (things like income and the costs of goods). In
models of rational utility maximizing behavior, people respond in predictable
ways to changes in the constraints they face. Do people in the real world
maximize behavior? I don’t know. I don’t care? I can’t observe their utility. I
can observe changes in constraints, and I can observe changes in behavior, and
I can assess the degree to which the changes in behavior are consistent with
the predictions of the model. I can’t say whether some person will think that
voting is a good, but I can predict if the cost of voting increases they are
less likely to do it.
As an economist I take people’s preferences as they are.
Personally, I may find attendance at stock car race to be more bad than good, but
as an economist it is not my business to tell other people that they should not
get utility from it. The fundamental difference between economists and the Pope
is that telling people what they should want is an essential part of his job as
Pope. The Pope is not taking preferences as given and trying to make
predictions about behavior. I stated before that people’s preferences tend to come
from culture, personal history, and individual tendencies. The Pope, as well as
other religious leaders and many secular leaders, do not take people’s
preferences as given. They want to shape those preferences. They try to
persuade us that we should get satisfaction from one thing rather than another.
They try to persuade us that we will be happier if we consume more prayer and
charity rather than more cars and marble counter tops.
Ultimately, economists have no more business complaining
about the Pope trying to persuade people that they will gain more satisfaction
from consuming prayer, penance, and charity than they do complaining about
Apple trying to persuade people that they will gain more satisfaction from a
Mac than a PC.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)