This is a blog about economics, history, law and other things that interest me.
Wednesday, May 29, 2019
Gavin Wright on Slavery and Anglo-American Capitalism
Gavin Wright's Tawney Lecture Slavery and Anglo-American Capitalism Revisited is now available
Thursday, May 9, 2019
Public Goods, Private Roads, and the Case of Scandinavia
In We Can
Build the Roads, and Other Things Too Mike Munger argues that roads are not
public goods and that the examples of Sweden and Finland support this argument.
I think there are a few problems with this argument.
One problem arises from the way we tend to explain public
goods in economics. We tell students that they are non-rival and non-excludable.
Rival means that one person’s use of a good diminishes the benefit for other
users: if you drink my coffee that will diminish the benefit that I get from
it. Excludable means that it is possible to exclude other people from using a good
at a reasonable cost. In fact, I generally do not have any problem keeping
people for drinking my coffee. The most common example of a public good is
national defense. The benefit you get from us not being invaded by North Korea does
not diminish the benefit I get from it, and it would be very difficult to
exclude either of us from those benefits. The problem with public goods is that
because people can get the benefit without paying, they will tend to free ride,
and the good will be underprovided. Munger points out that that roads are often
rival and people can be excluded. Interstate 95, which runs through
Fredericksburg, is a good example. Heavy traffic makes it rival more often than
not, and we have new toll lanes that you have to pay to use.
Munger notes that what most people think of as public goods, things like roads and public education, are not “pure public goods.” But it is not unreasonable for people to think of many of these things as “public goods,” in the sense of things that the state may have a role in providing, even if they are not “pure” public goods. Rivalry and excludability are matters of degree, and to the extent that something has the characteristics of non-rivalry and non-excludability positive externalities tend to exist. While I may be able to exclude you from direct access to the good, I can’t completely prevent you from getting some of the benefits. When the fire department puts out the fire in my house, you are better off because it won’t spread to yours. Yes, I can exclude people from a school and after a point it becomes rival, but if someone does get an education, I can’t exclude other people from benefiting from that as well. I can exclude people from getting flu shots, but I can’t exclude them from the benefits of others getting the shot. What people tend to think of as public goods are goods that many people believe to have significant positive externalities. Standard economic theory tells us that the market equilibrium will tend to underprovide goods with positive externalities, and that government action (or possibly some other sort of cooperative action) might be able to move society to a point where the marginal benefit to society and the marginal cost to society are closer to being equated. Just because you can have a private road, or a private school, or private security does not prove that there are not benefits to public provision of education, and roads, and police.
Not only are rivalry and excludability matters of degree, they
are not necessarily the same in all situations. A road is a piece of land that
can be used by some sort of traffic. Merely being a road does not make
something inherently public or private. The question “Are roads public goods?’
doesn’t really make sense. If I owned a
ranch in Wyoming and built a road on that ranch, nothing about that road would
make it a public good. Similarly, if I build a road in a new housing development
that only connects to one public road way there are unlikely to be benefits to people
who do not live there and excluding people is unlikely to be an issue. On the
other hand, the street that I live on in downtown Fredericksburg is non-rival
most of the time and it is hard to imagine any scheme for excluding people that
would be worth the cost. Personally, I am perfectly happy paying my taxes and
not having to participate in its management.
The broader point about economics here is that we shouldn’t
think of economic models as a bunch of bins to sort things into: “This goes
into public goods. That goes in common property.” Or “This market goes in
perfect competition; that one goes in monopoly.” Instead, the models help us to
understand the influence of things like rivalry, excludability, product
differentiation, and barriers to entry. All of which are matters of degree, not
simply yes or no.
What about the examples of Sweden and Finland? Munger suggests
that they support his argument that roads are not public goods:
A recent report from
the Devoe L. Moore Center gives this description:
Two-thirds of roads
in Sweden are privately operated and managed by local Private Road Associations
(PRAs). These road associations are composed of homeowners who live along
private roads. An estimated 140,000 kilometers (about 87,000 miles) of roads
are the responsibility of 60,000 PRAs…. The costs of upkeep are divided among members
of the association. PRAs that do not accept government subsidies can prohibit
traffic at their discretion. Those that receive subsidies must allow all
vehicles to travel on their roads.
Private ownership by
PRAs has proven to be a cost-effective measure for operating roads according to
the the Swedish government. In 2001, a government-commissioned evaluation found
PRAs could run their roads at about half the cost as for the national.
Finland employs a
similar system. Many private roads are managed by local cooperatives. Finland
has 78,000 kilometers (about 48,500 miles) of public roads and 280,000
kilometers (about 174,000 miles) of private roads. Of the 5 million people who
live in Finland, around 700,000 of them reside near a private road. Like Swedish
PRAs, Finnish cooperatives are made up of homeowners who live proximate to
private roads. These homeowners collectively maintain their local roads and are
eligible to receive subsidies from the federal government to cover a portion of
their expenses.
There are two lessons
here, and both are important.
First, many of the
things we expect from the state are not public goods. They could be more
efficiently and effectively handled by other kinds of cooperation.
Second, roads in
particular are emphatically not public goods, and many other nations have
solved the problems of road use and financing by decentralizing provision and
control. For some reason, the U.S. has allowed itself to become a socialized
road system, with no sense of any local ability to improve roads, fix potholes,
or cooperate with your neighbors. With available technology, and with the even
better technology now being developed,
roads can be operated locally and voluntarily. And that’s actually true for
many activities we now simply assume are restricted to the state. Some creative
rethinking can put us on the road to a better tomorrow.
This description makes the private roads in Sweden and
Finland sound very important, and it seems to imply that we don’t have private
roads in the United States.
Private roads in Sweden and Finland account for a lot of
miles but very little traffic. This is from a
paper by Sven Ivarsson, vice chairman of the Board of the National Federation
for Private Road Associations in Sweden, and Christina Malmberg Calvo, the
World Bank.
“The Swedish road
network measures 419,000 kilometers (see Table 1). The Swedish National Road
Administration (SNRA) manages one quarter of the network (98,000 kilometers),
and the municipalities 10 percent (38,000 kilometers). The remaining two thirds
(283,000 kilometers) are privately owned and managed roads. The SNRA roads
carry 70 percent of the traffic, the municipal roads 26 percent of the traffic,
and the private roads the remaining 4 percent of the traffic. While the private
roads arguably constitute a low volume network, some serve vacation home areas
and about 50 percent are forest roads mainly opened for commercial purposes,
about one third of the private roads carry more than 100 vehicles per day,
including some up to a 1,000 vehicles per day throughout the year. This paper
focuses principally on the 50 percent of the private road network which is
owned and managed by communities, half of which receive state subsidies.”
The situation is similar in Finland. In the 1990s,
“Finland has a
surface area of 338 000 km2 and 5 million inhabitants. The road system includes
105 000 km of private roads in residential areas, 77 000 km of public roads
maintained by the Finnish National Road Administration (FinnRA), and 23 000 km
of city streets and municipal roads maintained by local authorities. Traffic
volume on private roads is approximately 1000 million km per year, which is 2.5
percent of the total traffic volume in Finland.” Tiina
Korte Also like Sweden many of the roads are through forests, and about 70%
of lumber starts on private roads.
Private roads carry 4% of traffic in Sweden and 2.5% in
Finland. I don’t know what percentage private roads carry in the United States.
That’s right, there are private roads in the United States. As a matter of
fact, there have pretty much always been private roads in the United States. Private
roads were very important in early America. A lot of research has been done on
such roads by people like John Majewski, Dan Klein and Daniel Bogart (see here
for instance). There are still many private roads. If you have spent any time in rural areas, you
have probably come across signs on roads that say “Private Property. No Trespassing.”
Private roads run to some rural homes, and across private forests, farms and
ranches. Here is a template
for a private road agreement provided by Orange County, VA. The agreement provides for a group of people
to privately provide for a road.
Points 4 through 7 are interesting
(4)
No public responsibility. Said construction and maintenance is under no
circumstances a responsibility of the County, Virginia Department of
Transportation (VDOT), the Commonwealth Transportation Board, or any other
public entity.
(5)
Emergency services. It is understood that failure of the owners
to adequately maintain the Roadway may inhibit the ability of the County to
provide emergency services to the parcels, any liability for which shall be
borne among the owners.
(6)
School bus service. The provision of Orange County public school
bus services on this private road are not guaranteed or implied. The suitability for any private road for
school bus services and routes shall remain at the discretion of the Orange
County School Board.
(7)
Liability. It is understood that the County and its agents shall not be liable or responsible in any
manner to the developer or the property owners along the road, or to their
contractors, subcontractors, agents, or any other person, firm or corporation,
for any debt, claim, demand, damages, action or causes of action of any kind or
character arising out of or by reason of the activities or improvements being
required herein. It shall not be
eligible for acceptance into the State Secondary System of State Highways for
maintenance until such time as it is constructed and otherwise complies with
all requirements of the Virginia Department of Transportation for the addition
of subdivision roads current at the time of such request. Any costs required to cause this road to
become eligible for addition to the State system shall be provided from funds
other than those administered by the Virginia Department of Transportation and
by Orange County.
The difference between the Scandinavian examples and the U.S
example is that Orange County is telling people who want a private road not to
expect anything from the government. People in Sweden and Finland, on the other
hand, appear to believe that there are positive externalities associated with
maintaining the population even in remote parts of the country, and, therefore,
subsidize low volume private roads in those parts of the country.
Monday, May 6, 2019
More Evo-Nonsense
Occasionally, Evonomics provides something useful. For
instance, it re-ran the blog post “Where do pro-Social
institutions Come From? How Do Countries ‘Get to Denmark’? by Pseudoerasmus.
Unfortunately, much of the
time it runs critiques of “economics” by people who do not know anything about
economics.
Here for example is Nick Hanauer writing about “How
to Kill Neoliberalism Kill “Homo Economicus”:
I believe that these
corrosive moral claims derive from a fundamentally flawed understanding of how
market capitalism works, grounded in the dubious assumption that human beings
are “homo economicus”: perfectly selfish, perfectly rational, and
relentlessly self-maximizing. It is this behavioral model upon which all the
other models of orthodox economics are built. And it is nonsense.
The last 40 years of
research across multiple scientific disciplines has proven, with certainty,
that homo economicus does not exist. Outside of economic models, this is simply
not how real humans behave. Rather, Homo sapiens have evolved to be
other-regarding, reciprocal, heuristic, and intuitive moral creatures. We can
be selfish, yes—even cruel. But it is our highly evolved prosocial nature—our
innate facility for cooperation, not competition—that has enabled our species
to dominate the planet, and to build such an extraordinary—and extraordinarily
complex—quality of life. Pro-sociality is our economic super power.
What is nonsense is that economic theory is built on the
assumption that human beings are “perfectly
selfish, perfectly rational, and relentlessly self-maximizing.”
Here is Gary Becker on the meaning of rationality
“What is meant by
rational behavior? Consider first what is not meant. Certainly not that people
are necessarily selfish, “economic men” solely concerned with their own well-being.
This would rule out charity and love for children, spouses relatives or anyone
else, and a model of rational behavior could not be so grossly inconsistent
with actual behavior and still be useful.”
“The essence of the
model of rational behavior is contained in just two assumptions: each consumer
has an ordered set of preferences, and he choses the most preferred position
available to him.” (Becker Economic
Theory page 26)
Show me where the sort of description of rationality that
Hanauer puts forward appears in economics. I looked in my old copies of Varian
and Silberberg. It wasn’t there. Checked
Mankiw’s principles text. Not there either. You can find assumptions about the
consistency of preferences, but where do you find anything about what people
are supposed to prefer? There is no more reason for economists to say that
people can’t get utility from charity than there is for economists to say that
you can’t get utility from eating apples.
If we want to improve economics we need to start from where
it actually is, not with some imagined boogeyman of homo economicus.
There are plenty of things we could do better. We could teach
more history. We could place less emphasis on advanced math. We could try to get
faculty and students that look more like the society we live in. But you aren’t
going improve economics by assuming an imaginary homo economicus who isn’t there.
Friday, April 26, 2019
Why Tyler Cowen is wrong about the Wizard of Oz
ATWOOD: Let’s
talk about The Wizard of
Oz.
COWEN: Sure.
ATWOOD: Now,
there’s an absolutely core to the American psyche —
COWEN: It’s
an economics movie. It’s about bimetallism, right? The yellow brick road is
about the gold standard? This is not commonly known, but it’s true.
[laughter]
COWEN: It’s
a monetary allegory, the whole movie.
ATWOOD: You
think so?
COWEN: I know so.
ATWOOD: You
know a lot of things. So, the Tin Woodman is what in it?
COWEN: He’s
one of the people in the bimetallist debates. But there was a Journal of
Political Economy article going
through all of the parallels.
ATWOOD: And
Dorothy is what?
COWEN: I
think just the innocent American crying for relief.
ATWOOD: Are
you buying any of this? I’m not.
[laughter]
ATWOOD: And
the tornado is?
COWEN: Maybe
depression, deflation.
ATWOOD: And
Toto is?
COWEN: That
one I’m stumped on.
[laughter]
ATWOOD: The
flying monkeys are?
COWEN: William
Jennings Bryan?
ATWOOD: Okay.
Well, here’s the really interesting thing about Wizard of Oz. In The Wizard of Oz, the male wizard is a fraud,
and all of the other male characters are missing something.
COWEN: That’s
right.
ATWOOD: Yes.
But the witches are real. Now, Tyler, I’m going to tell you a story.
Someone posted this part of the conversation on twitter and
I replied by saying it should be filed under things that Tyler knows that are
not so and added a link to a paper I published on the Wizard of Oz. Cowen replied,
I'm sticking with the JPE on this one, sorry!
I asked why,
but he did not explain.
Cowen does not seem to be particularly familiar with the JPE
article. A link was added in the transcript, but the author, Hugh Rockoff, isn’t
mentioned in the interview. Rockoff’s paper
does not have anything to do with the movie. The allegory story doesn’t work well
with the movie because of changes from the book. For instance, in the book the
slippers were silver and the Emerald City was fake; it only looked emerald
because visitors were forced to wear green glasses. Moreover, Cowen does not
seem to know what the characters in the Wizard of Oz are supposed to represent
in this allegory. In Rockoff’s paper the Tin Woodman is the working man and the
Cowardly Lion is William Jennings Bryan. Yet Cowen does not just think that it
is an allegory he knows it. After all, it was published in the Journal of Political Economy.
I really am curious why he is sticking with the JPE because I have a hard time seeing how anyone can read both the original JPE paper and my paper and still find the monetary allegory interpretation persuasive. Academics can have legitimate disputes, but at some point the amount of evidence falling on one side of the dispute should be able to tip the scales even if the original paper was published in JPE.
For those unfamiliar with the interpretation of Oz as a
monetary allegory it goes something like this:
“In 1964,
Henry Littlefield, a high school history teacher, described what appeared to be
numerous coincidences between The Wonderful Wizard of Oz and the Populist
movement of the late 19th century. Once viewed through a Populist lens, the
symbolism of the book appears incredibly obvious. The Scarecrow represents
farmers, the Tin Woodman represents industrial workers, and the Cowardly Lion
represents William Jennings Bryan.' Dorothy was told to follow a yellow brick
road-the gold standard. People in the Emerald City were forced to look at
everything through green glasses-greenbacks. The silver shoes-coinage of
silver-really had the power to take Dorothy home. Oz itself refers to the
abbreviation for an ounce of gold.” (Hansen 2002, 255)
What evidence does Rockoff provide in the JPE paper?
(Rockoff 1990, 756)
Rockoff states that there is no direct evidence, and in my
paper I argue that here was no circumstantial evidence either. It was not
discovered independently numerous times. No one noticed in until Henry Littlefield
came up with the idea as an exercise to get high school students thinking about
the Populist movement. What is known about Baum’s politics also does not
support the argument that it was written as a monetary allegory (see Hansen
2002, 257-260).
Cowen added in another tweet reply that he was also going
with this
book review by J. Jackson Barlow. But neither Barlow nor the authors that
he reviews argue that the story was written as a monetary allegory. Barlow’s
interpretation is consistent with Baum’s claims that he was writing a fairy
tale for modern times.
Read Hugh’s paper and read my paper (it is short and easy to
read) and decide for yourself.
Atwood's insights were more consistent with what is known about Baum: one of the few political issues that he really cared about was the suffrage movement. By the way, he was married to Maud Gage, daughter of Matilda Joslyn Gage.
Thursday, April 18, 2019
Historians and Economists
This is a short list of book
reviews that I think support an argument that I have been making for a while
now about the relationship between economic and historical research.
Oakes, James. "Capitalism
and slavery and the civil war." International Labor and
Working-Class History 89 (2016): 195 -220.
Coclanis, Peter A. "Slavery,
Capitalism, and the Problem of Misprision." Journal of
American Studies 52, no. 3
(2018).
Logan, Trevon D. "The
Republic for Which it Stands: The United States During Reconstruction and the
Gilded Age, 1865–1896. By Richard White. New York, NY: Oxford, 2017. Pp.
xx, 94. $35.00, hardcover." The Journal of Economic History 79,
no. 1 (2019): 305-308.
Hansen, B.A., 2019. Brahmin
Capitalism: Frontiers of Wealth and Populism in America’s First Gilded Age. By
Noam Maggor. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2017. Pp. ix, 284.
$39.95, hardcover. The Journal of Economic History, 79(1),
pp.304-305.
Pseudoerasmus recently brought the
Oakes review to may attention and spoke very highly of it. I agree that it is an outstanding review. I also think that together
with several recent reviews it supports my argument that critiques of historians
of capitalism by economic historians are not based on any fundamental
methodological difference between economics and history. Instead, economic
historians have largely been criticizing historians of capitalism for their
failure to follow traditional standards of historical scholarship in their treatment
of both primary and secondary sources. The first two are reviews of works by
historians of capitalism by historians, who raise many of the same concerns
that economists have. The second two are positive reviews by economists of recent
work by historians associated with the history of capitalism.
Oakes reviews
Walter Johnson , River
of Dark Dreams: Slavery and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom . Cambridge :
Harvard University Press , 2013. 561 pp. $35.00.
Edward E. Baptist , The
Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism .
New York : Basic Books , 2014. 528 pp. $35.00.
Sven Beckert , Empire
of Cotton: A Global History . New York : Alfred A. Knopf , 2014. 640 pp.
$35.00.
Calvin Schermerhorn , The
Business of Slavery and the Rise of American Capitalism, 1815-1860 . New
Haven : Yale University Press , 2015. 352 pp. $65.00.
Coclanis reviews
Sven Beckert and Seth Rothman (eds.), Slavery’s Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development
(Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Here is Oakes take on Baptist’s claims about the economic
impact of slavery.
Baptist's most extravagant and least
persuasive claim is that all of the prosperity of the American
economy derived from slavery. There's barely a sentence in his book that could
justify such a claim, however, and for a very obvious reason: Any study aimed
at calculating the impact of slavery for northern economic development would
not be a book about slavery at all. It would have to be a book about the North.
At the very least, The Half Has Never Been Told would require
a second half that examines the process of economic development in the free
states and demonstrates precisely when and how that process depended on
southern slavery. That will not be easy, at least not based on the
extraordinary scholarship of the last generation or two.
Consider the outcome
of the debate among scholars that raged through the 1980s over the
transformation of the northern countryside. There is now broad agreement that
farmers in the northern colonies always produced surpluses for sale although
they were careful to limit their market involvement in ways that protected
their economic independence. That began to change in the 1790s, when New
England farmers found themselves trapped by the competitive demands of a
rapidly commercializing agriculture in ways that forced them to steadily
increase their productivity. The process spread westward, and the northern
countryside was thoroughly transformed by 1845, when wheat farmers began to
mechanize production at an astonishing pace.17Northern agricultural
productivity skyrocketed even as the rural economy extruded "surplus"
population into cities and factories at a rate that outpaced number of
immigrants--who were by then streaming into the North by the millions. Those
landless workers were attracted by a new form of free labor that had
simultaneously developed in the North in the decades following the American
Revolution. Apprentice contracts became wage contracts, indentured servitude
disappeared, and slavery was abolished. By the 1820s "a day's pay for a
day's work" became the norm--and with it a uniquely mobile population of
free laborers was created. Within the space of a single lifetime forms of
long-term labor subordination that had existed for centuries, even millennia,
were dramatically overthrown. "Thus it was not slavery," Gavin Wright
has concluded, "but the post-Revolutionary abolitions and the exclusion of
slavery from the Northwest Territory that launched the American economy on its
modern trajectory."18Put these two developments together--the
transformation of the northern countryside and the rapidly expanding population
of highly mobile wage laborers--and the stage was set for the dynamic
interaction of the city and the country that so many scholars have seen as the
preeminent characteristic of northern economic development.19
None of this appears
in Baptist's account. Instead, he disinters an older story that told of
industrialization "spiraling outward" from the textile mills of
Massachusetts and Rhode Island--a story long ago abandoned by most economic
historians. Before we revert to this traditional account, however, Baptist will
have to explain where historians like Diane Lindstrom went wrong when they
adduced evidence that the southern trade was relatively unimportant to the economic
development of the Philadelphia. He would have to explain away the evidence
that "metropolitan industrialization" overshadowed New York City's
ties to slavery, that economic development bound the city much more closely to
the wheat and dairy farmers in the Hudson, Mohawk, and Ohio River valleys--as
most scholars now believe. He would have to explain away the extraordinary maps
in William Cronon's Nature's Metropolis demonstrating the
way railroads spread out from Chicago bringing wheat farmers throughout the
Midwest into the city's powerful economic orbit--an orbit that reached back to
the east coast and all the way to Europe but that barely touched the slave
states. In these accounts the history of the northern economy after 1776 is one
of growing independence from slavery, a fact of no small
significance for the origins of the Civil War.
In addition to explaining where generations
of scholarship on northern economic development have gone wrong, Baptist would
have to tell us where he's getting his numbers. He points out that in 1836
cotton production represented about five percent of the gross domestic product.
This is a widely accepted statistic, having been calculated in several
different ways by a number of different scholars. But its significance is not
self-evident. Is five percent a lot or a little? Instead of addressing that
question, however, Baptist quickly moves on to the second- and third-order
effects of cotton in the larger economy, and here a number of problems arise.
To begin with, second-order effects are notoriously difficult to calculate, and
by the time you get to third-order effects, you might as well be floating in
the clouds. At the very least, such calculations require extensive
justification and analytical precision--none of which Baptist provides. In
fact, he provides no sources whatsoever for any of his calculations. From his
brief description he seems to be adding the proceeds of wealth transfers--such
as the sale of slaves--to the figures for output. Finally, having posited suspiciously
large second- and third-order effects, he then adds those
effects to the original GDP statistic, and suddenly, without explanation, five
percent becomes fifty percent. Obviously if you applied the same technique to
every other northern enterprise--the granaries of the Midwest, the printing
shops of Manhattan, the iron foundries of Pennsylvania, the small manufacturers
of Philadelphia, the meatpackers of Cincinnati, the dairy farmers of the Hudson
Valley, the wheat farmers along the Erie Canal--you would end up with five
thousand percent of the GDP. If Baptist's numbers were even remotely accurate,
the abolition of slavery during the Civil War would have been accompanied by a
catastrophic collapse of the northern economy.
Baptist takes his
title from Lorenzo Ivy, one of the many elderly ex-slaves interviewed by the
WPA in the 1930s. Ivy and his mother were originally owned by a
"mean" master who broke up families left and right. Ivy told the
interviewer that the only good thing his heartless owner ever did, and did
unintentionally, was to sell the boy and his mother to his father's owner. This
endless buying and selling of slaves--the coffles of chained human beings who
passed by Ivy's Virginia home year after year--is the "half" of
slavery's history that Baptist claims has never been told. But Baptist himself
doesn't tell the other half of the ex-slave's own story. Ivy described his new
master as a good man who kept the slave family together, recognized the boy's
talent as a shoemaker, sent him off to Lynchburg to learn the trade, and let
Ivy hire himself out. Ivy's mistress taught the boy to read. When the Civil War
ended, Ivy was sufficiently literate and skilled to set up his own shoemaking
shop and attend Hampton Institute. He was at Hampton when his former master
died, and Ivy was upset that he was unable to attend the funeral to pay his
respects.20”
This is from near the end of Coclanis’ review
“One assumes that the
editors and most of the authors of Slavery’s Capitalism are coming from one or
another critical political-economy position, but which one is difficult, if not
impossible, to tell.
This would not be the
case had the editors and authors engaged more directly with work written before
they started scribbling, a point also made by Scott R. Nelson in an important
assessment of the NHAC movement. And here I do not just mean theoretical work
on the history of capitalism – the huge internal literatures in the Marxist and
marxisant traditions, most notably – but the equally large empirical
literatures by historians and economists writing about capitalism and slavery
within the context of the United States. Since the mid-1950s, “new” economic
historians have been wrestling with questions concerned with slavery and
capitalism, and the relationship between slavery and capitalism became central
to the entire “new” economic history project beginning in the late 1960s and
remained so until the early 1990ss. But this seems like ancient history – so
yesterday – to many devotees of the NHAC. And American historians, likewise,
were wrestling with similar issues at the same time. Not only Eugene Genovese
and Elizabeth Fox-Genovese either, but also their students, as well as dozens
of other scholars, who came at such issues from a variety of points of view.
Here, we can start with names such as Hal Woodman, Jim Oakes, Allan Kulikoff,
Lorena Walsh, John McCusker, Russ Menard, Drew McCoy, Laurence Shore, Barbara
Fields, Joseph Reidy, Steven Hahn, Rachel Klein, Joyce Chaplin, Lacy Ford,
Robin Blackburn, Shearer Davis Bowman, etc. For my part, I wrote an entire book
in 1989 wherein I dealt directly with the relationship between slavery and
capitalism, and, in so doing, dealt explicitly with matters regarding the definition
of capitalism, among other concerns. Now Beckert for one knows all of this. He
has previously acknowledged some of the scholars mentioned above – those operating
in what he sees as the political-economy tradition – as “distinguished
antecedents.” But in Slavery’s Capitalism such acknowledgment is nowhere to be
found, lost perhaps in the frisson of excitement that the NHAC initiative has
evoked.
All of which brings
me to my final points, involving misrepresentation and scholarly comity. As the
paragraphs above suggest, neither Slavery’s Capitalism specifically nor the NHAC
more generally accurately captures and conveys economists’ and historians’ engagement
with the questions treated in Slavery’s Capitalism and the issues of concern to
new historians of American capitalism.”
These are essentially the same claims that economists have
made about Baptist’s misuse of both the previous literature and primary
sources. Oakes also provides the most critical review of Johnson that I have
come across. He is, however, not entirely critical of their work. He finds more
to value in Baptist than I do. And although he is very critical, his motivation
is not just to tear down (I have to admit that when it comes to Baptist, I personally
want to not leave a single brick standing). Oakes and Coclanis, on the other seems
to want to push the new historians of capitalism in productive directions. Most
importantly they want them to integrate their work with earlier work on capitalism,
slavery, and its origins. By the way, here is my review of Slavery's Capitalism
Economists Logan and Hansen, in contrast, provide
favorable reviews of more recent work by people associated with the history of
capitalism. I’m not sure that Richard White is as strongly associated with the
New History of Capitalism as people like Beckert, Baptist, Johnson or Levy, but
he could make a reasonable claim to having been at it longer. One of the common
features of both books are that, in contrast, some of the work criticized by
Coclanis and Oakes, both White and Maggor attempt to integrate the work of
people, including economists, who have worked in their field. I had previously
noted this in regard to one element of White’s book, the evidence on material
well-being in the late nineteenth century. Although I disagreed with his conclusion, my argument was based primarily on very recent research. Some of which
probably wasn’t even available at the time he was writing. I believe that White
was probably using the estimates that were most widely accepted by economic
historians at the time he was writing.
The books by White and Maggor are not economic history as economists typically
do it now, but each has something interesting to say. Economists and historians
do not have to use the same methods or even ask the same questions. What is essential
is that where there is overlap we need to honestly acknowledge and address each
other’s work. If a historian is interested investment in the west during the
nineteenth century, they should at least note what economists have had to say
about interregional capital flows, as Maggor does. Conversely, if an economist
is interested in the development of state and local institutions intended to
promote or regulate these investments, they should read what Maggor says.
Sunday, March 3, 2019
Some Recent Economic History of Slavery and Its Political and Economic Legacy
The other day on twitter,
Seth Rockman and I were discussing current work on slavery by economic
historians. He thought that there was “more energy being spent policing
"driving force" claims than in generating new findings about
how/where slavery mattered to broader economic transformations.” I told him
that refuting claims like those made by Ed Baptist really doesn’t take that
much effort, and I suggested a list of people that he might want to look at to
see where the energy of economic historians was actually going. This is a much
fuller list than I provided in the tweet, and it provides citations and links (wherever
possible to ungated versions). There are a couple of papers that go back about
ten years, but I think most of the published papers are within the last five
years. Some are still working papers.
As the title of the
post suggests the list includes both papers that are directly about slavery and
papers that are about the political and economic legacy of slavery. Most are
specifically about the U.S. since that is the area I know best, and I tried to
stay focused on economic history, i.e. research that is about understanding the
past. There is also a large literature that focuses on tracing current
conditions to the existence of slavery in the past, see e.g. Nathan Nunn;
Yeonha Jung "How
the Legacy of Slavery Survives: Labor Market Institutions and Demand for Human
Capital." (2018); or Graziella Bertocchi and Arcangelo Dimico. "Slavery,
education, and inequality." European Economic Review 70 (2014): 197-209.
In addition, if you are
interested in recent work on the Atlantic slave trade you might start with Warren Whatley and Rob Gillezeau, or work in progress by Ellora
Derenoncourt “Atlantic Slavery’s Impact on European and British Economic
Development.” Finally, there are other interesting working papers that I know of,
but I try to honor the wishes of authors when they request that preliminary
work not be cited or circulated. You will have to find those papers yourself.
Bodenhorn, Howard. The color factor: The economics
of African-American well-being in the nineteenth-century South. Oxford University
Press, USA, 2015.
Calomiris, Charles W.,
and Jonathan Pritchett. "Betting
on secession: Quantifying political events surrounding slavery and the civil
war." American Economic Review 106, no. 1 (2016): 1-23.
Carruthers, Celeste K.,
and Marianne H. Wanamaker. "Separate
and unequal in the labor market: human capital and the jim crow wage
gap." Journal of Labor Economics 35, no. 3 (2017): 655-696.
Collins, William J.,
and Robert A. Margo.
"Race and Home Ownership from the End of the Civil War to the
Present." American Economic Review 101, no. 3 (2011): 355-59.
Collins, William J.,
and Marianne H. Wanamaker. Up from slavery? African American
intergenerational economic mobility since 1880.
No. w23395. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2017.
Cook, Lisa D. "Violence
and economic activity: evidence from African American patents, 1870–1940." Journal of Economic Growth 19, no. 2
(2014): 221-257.
Cook, Lisa D., Trevon
D. Logan, and John M. Parman. "Racial segregation and southern
lynching." Social Science History42, no. 4 (2018): 635-675. Summary
here.
Craig, Lee A., and
Robert G. Hammond. "Nutrition and signaling in slave markets: a new look
at a puzzle within the antebellum puzzle." Cliometrica 7,
no. 2 (2013): 189-206.
González, Felipe,
Guillermo Marshall, and Suresh Naidu. "Start-up nation? slave
wealth and entrepreneurship in civil war Maryland." The
Journal of Economic History 77, no. 2 (2017): 373-405.
Hornbeck, Richard, and
Suresh Naidu. "When the
levee breaks: black migration and economic development in the American
South." American Economic Review 104, no. 3 (2014): 963-90.
Lander, Kevin, and
Jonathan Pritchett. "When to
Care: The Economic Rationale of Slavery Health Care Provision." Social
Science History 33, no. 2
(2009): 155-182.
Lennon, Conor. "Slave
escape, prices, and the fugitive slave act of 1850." The Journal of Law and
Economics 59, no. 3 (2016):
669-695.
Logan, Trevon D. Do
Black Politicians Matter?. No.
w24190. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2018.
Logan, Trevon D. "A
Time (Not) Apart: A Lesson in Economic History from Cotton Picking
Books." The Review of Black Political Economy 42, no. 4
(2015): 301-322.
Logan, Trevon D., and
Jonathan B. Pritchett. "On
the marital status of US slaves: Evidence from Touro Infirmary, New Orleans,
Louisiana." Explorations in Economic History 69 (2018): 50-63.
Miller, Melinda C. "Land
and racial wealth inequality." American Economic Review 101,
no. 3 (2011): 371-76.
Miller, Melinda C.
"Destroyed by slavery? Slavery and African American family formation
following emancipation." Demography 55, no. 5
(2018): 1587-1609.
Naidu, Suresh. Suffrage, schooling, and sorting
in the post-bellum US South. No. w18129. National Bureau of Economic
Research, 2012.
Olmstead, Alan L., and
Paul W. Rhode. "Cotton,
slavery, and the new history of capitalism." Explorations in Economic
History 67 (2018):
1-17.
Price, Gregory N.,
William A. Darity Jr, and Alvin E. Headen Jr. "Does
the stigma of slavery explain the maltreatment of blacks by whites?: The case
of lynchings." The Journal of Socio-Economics 37, no. 1
(2008): 167-193.
Pritchett, Jonathan,
and Jessica Hayes. "The occupations of slaves sold in New Orleans: Missing
values, cheap talk, or informative advertising?." Cliometrica 10,
no. 2 (2016): 181-195.
Sacerdote, Bruce. "Slavery and the
intergenerational transmission of human capital." Review of Economics and
Statistics 87, no. 2
(2005): 217-234.
Steckel, Richard H.,
and Nicolas Ziebarth. "A
troublesome statistic: Traders and coastal shipments in the westward movement
of slaves." The Journal of Economic History 73, no. 3
(2013): 792-809.
Steckel, Richard H.,
and Nicolas Ziebarth. "Trader Selectivity and Measured Catch-Up Growth of
American Slaves." The Journal of Economic History 76, no. 1 (2016): 109-138.
Sutch, Richard C. The
Economics of African American Slavery: The Cliometrics Debate. No.
w25197. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2018.
Wanamaker, Marianne H.
"Fertility and the
Price of Children: Evidence from Slavery and Slave Emancipation." The Journal of Economic History 74, no. 4
(2014): 1045-1071.
Sunday, February 17, 2019
The Newer History of Capitalism
Robert Wright has a blog post about Why
the History of Capitalism Subfield Got Slavery (and Almost Everything Else) so
Terribly Wrong His argument is that because history departments
abandoned economic and business history, there was no one with expertise in
these subjects to guide new scholars when interest in economic issues re-emerged.
The evidence that history departments largely abandoned economic and business history
is irrefutable, and I certainly wish that they would pursue his remedy of
hiring some highly qualified economic and business historians. However, I am
not entirely persuaded by his argument. I am not persuaded because I think that
the problems he points to arose more from the failure to follow traditional
standards of historical research than lack of knowledge in economics. In
addition, at least some recent scholars working in “the history of capitalism”
subfield seem to have found ways to deal with lack of expertise within history
departments.
The problem with the work of people like Baptist and Levy is
less the bad economics than the bad history. It is true that Baptist is
arrogantly ignorant of economics, but it is not clear that the problem of Baptist’s
misrepresentation of the historiography of slavery would have been resolved by
a little more knowledge of economics. One only needs access to google to
discover that his claim that before him most economists and historians believed
that slavery was inefficient was false. His procedure for estimating the
economic importance of slave produced cotton is nonsense, but the biggest
problem is that he made up the numbers that he used. Even if he had paid
attention in Principles of Macroeconomics and used something resembling
national income accounting, his calculations still would have produced crap because
he think it is okay to just make up evidence rather than deriving it from historical
sources. Yes, Baptist does not understand the meaning of the term productivity,
but the bigger problem is that he misrepresents the sources that he claims to
be using to explain productivity growth. He claims that slaves used the term “pushing
system” but it is not in the narrative that he cites or any other source that
anyone has presented. He re-wrote the story of the whipping machine from Henry
Clay’s narrative to make it fit his argument. Narratives that he relies upon generally
paint a much different picture of picking than Baptist. Baptist argues that enslaved
people under the force of harsher and harsher pushing were forced to develop
techniques to pick more quickly. To explain productivity increases in the antebellum
period these techniques can’t be unique to individuals they need to be passed
on and further developed. In contrast, slave narratives frequently emphasize
inherent dexterity and the age at which one starts picking as determinants of
speed; there is no mention of innovations in picking techniques being handed
down. Here is a recent post that has links
to other posts about the numerous problems in Baptist’s work and here is
the post about his
rewriting of the story of the whipping machine.
Similarly, Levy’s sloppiness with sources seems to be the cause
of his confusion about economics rather than the other way around. Suggesting
that modern use of the term risk (and in fact risk itself) only dates to the
mid-nineteenth century is a failure historical scholarship not economics. Using
George Perkins as his source on the Panic of 1907 without any recognition that
many people regarded Perkins as one of the people who had perpetuated the Panic
is a failure of historical research not business or economic knowledge. Making Veblen’s
work the focus of a paper and then repeatedly cite them incorrectly is less a problem
arising from his lack knowledge of economics (most economists don’t know
anything about Veblen) than it is a problem arising from his sloppy handling
of his sources. Knowing a little more about economics is not going to help
someone who does not read carefully enough to know that Veblen was writing
about pecuniary magnates not pecuniary magnets. In other words, I do wish that
Baptist and Levy and others had tried to learn a bit more about economic and
business history before deciding to write about it, but their bad economics is
not nearly as much a problem as their bad history.
Economists might still disagree with them, but I don’t think
they would express as much hostility toward them if these historians of
capitalism had they displayed the skills generally associated with historical
training: accurate historiography, and careful and faithful use of their
sources.
The good news is that in the last year or so I have read good
books by historians, examining subjects that probably fit into the history of
capitalism subfield. A partial list of these books would include Noam Maggor’s Brahmin Capitalism, Anne Fleming’s City of Debtors: A Century of Fringe Finance,
Josh Lauer Creditworthy, Caitlin
Rosenthal Accounting for Slavery,
Daina Ramey Berry The Price of Their Pound of Flesh. I’m pretty sure from interaction on twitter that Maggor and
Rosenthal identify with “the history of capitalism” label, and Lauer’s book was
published in Columbia Studies in the History of U.S. Capitalism series. I did not see
in these books the problems that I identified in the earlier history of capitalism.
None of these is economic history the way it is typically written by economists
now, but the authors appeared to take advantage of the work of people in other
disciplines, including economics. Most mentioned at least one economist
economic historian in their acknowledgments, Caitlin Rosenthal and Daina Ramey Berry both thank
several economists. Even if experts in the field are not in your department,
they are out there, and there is a good chance they are willing to help. Keri Leigh Merritt is another example of a historian working on economics related issues who has gone out of her way to interact with economists.
In short, I am optimistic about the ability of historians
who want to write about economic and business history. I wish I was as
optimistic about the future of their ability to get good jobs
P.S. Wright also suggests that the work of people like
Baptist is driven in part by a desire to provide support for reparations.
Actually, it is probably more accurate to say that Wright is suggesting they
want to make a show of supporting reparations.
“The general gist of their story is that slavery made
America rich so its government ought to make restitution to the descendants of
slaves.”
I have to say I have never understood why reparations would
need to be justified by a showing of the amount of benefit derived from
slavery. In general, the law compensates people for the damage done to injured
not the benefit to the injurer.
Tuesday, February 5, 2019
Women in Economics
Marginal Revolution University is starting a series on Women in Economics.
It reminded me to post that the St. Louis Federal Reserve (which happens to be the best Fed) already has a podcast series on Women in Economics.
It reminded me to post that the St. Louis Federal Reserve (which happens to be the best Fed) already has a podcast series on Women in Economics.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)